• No results found

Economic Instruments in Environmental Policy

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Economic Instruments in Environmental Policy"

Copied!
268
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

)NSTRUMENTS

%NVIRONMENTAL

!

0ROTECTION

(2)

A report by the Swedish Environmental Protection Agency and the Swedish Energy Agency

SWEDISH ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION AGENCY

(3)

Internet: www.naturvardsverket.se/bokhandeln The Swedish Environmental Protection Agency Phone: + 46 (0)8-698 10 00, Fax: + 46 (0)8-20 29 25

E-mail: natur@naturvardsverket.se

Address: Naturvårdsverket, SE-106 48 Stockholm, Sweden Internet: www.naturvardsverket.se

ISBN 91-620-5678-6.pdf ISSN 0282-7298 © Naturvårdsverket 2007

Digital publication

Cover photos: Helt Enkelt/Johnér Bildbyrå Translation: Maxwell Arding

(4)

Preface

This report reviews existing economic instruments in the environmental field in Sweden. Evaluations of the various economic instruments have been summarised. Particular emphasis has been given to four of the16 environmental objectives in Swedish environmental policy and protection. These are Reduced Climate Impact, A Non-Toxic Environment, Sustainable Forests and Zero Eutrophication. A prob-lem common to these objectives is that they are considered to be very difficult to achieve within the stated deadline. The analysis made is also linked to the three action strategies: (i) More efficient energy use and transport; (ii) Non-toxic and resource-efficient cyclical systems; and (iii) Management of land, water and the built environment.

Our approach is based on the long-term socio-economically efficient use of struments to achieve environmental objectives. Since only a few evaluations in-clude socio-economic evaluation methods, we have defined three criteria for de-termining whether a given instrument is an effective long-term aid to achievement of the environmental objectives. Market-based systems, i.e. the electricity certifi-cate scheme and the EU emissions trading scheme, are not described separately; they are described to the extent the systems act in conjunction with other economic instruments. The economic instruments covered can be divided into groups: taxes, charges, tax relief and grants.

This project has been carried out over a fairly short space of time, and we have therefore been unable to fully review the literature. Nonetheless, our survey in-cludes nearly two hundred evaluations.

The project has been carried out by the Swedish EPA and the Swedish Energy Agency as directed by the Ministry of the Environment. There has also been con-sultation with the National Institute of Economic Research and the Swedish Tax Agency and other agencies responsible for environmental objectives or sectors. The study is a preliminary study in preparation for a government report on eco-nomic instruments and also forms part of the in-depth review of environmental objectives to be performed in 2008.

The following people have been involved in preparation of this report: Reino Abrahamsson (Swedish EPA), Johanna Andréasson (Swedish Energy Agency), Mats Björsell (Swedish EPA), Johanna Jussila Hammes (Swedish Energy Agency), Therese Karlsson (Swedish Energy Agency), Henrik Scharin (Swedish EPA), Ul-rika Lindstedt (Swedish EPA) and Pelle Magdalinski (Swedish EPA).

Project leaders were Marcus Carlsson Reich, Swedish EPA and Karin Sahlin, Swedish Energy Agency. English translation by Maxwell Arding.

(5)
(6)

Contents

PREFACE 3 CONTENTS 5

1 SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS 9

Summary of the need to evaluate economic instruments 21

2 BACKGROUND 25

3 INTRODUCTION 27

3.1 Purpose, method and scope 27

3.2 Structure of the report 28

3.3 Environmental objectives and other societal goals 28

3.4 Instruments to achieve the objectives 31

3.5 Socio-economically efficient use of instruments 32

3.5.1 Introduction 32

3.5.2 Theoretical considerations 33

3.5.3 Criteria for evaluating the effectiveness of instruments 35 3.5.4 Outline description of instruments and their effectiveness 39

4 ENVIRONMENTAL OBJECTIVES, STRATEGIES AND ECONOMIC

INSTRUMENTS USED 43

4.1 Reduced Climate Impact 43

4.1.1 Problems 45 4.1.2 Available instruments 47 4.1.3 Development potential 50 4.2 A Non-Toxic Environment 53 4.2.1 Available instruments 55 4.2.2 Development potential 56 4.3 Sustainable Forests 57 4.3.1 Economic instruments 60 4.3.2 Development potential 63 4.4 Zero Eutrophication 63 4.4.1 Available instruments 65 4.4.2 Development potential 66

4.5 Three action strategies and economic instruments used 70

4.5.1 More efficient energy use and transport 73

(7)

4.5.3 Management of land, water and the built environment 82

5 SURVEY OF INSTRUMENTS 85

5.1 Multi-sectoral 85

5.1.1 Energy and carbon dioxide taxes in outline 85

5.1.2 Sulphur tax 98

5.1.3 Klimp (local climate investment programmes) 99

5.1.4 Grants for market launch of energy-efficient technology 103 5.1.5 Relationship between instruments and environmental objectives and

strategies 105

5.2 Manufacturing industry and energy production 107

5.2.1 Energy and carbon dioxide tax and their lower rates 109 5.2.2 Financial support for wind power, including the environmental bonus 116 5.2.3 Programme for improved energy efficiency (PFE) 117

5.2.4 Property tax on hydropower and wind power 123

5.2.5 Tax on nuclear power output 125

5.2.6 The NOX charge 126

5.2.7 Relationship between instruments and environmental objectives and

strategies 128

5.2.8 Combined effects of instruments in industry 130

5.2.9 Company interviews 134

5.3 Housing and services etc 137

5.3.1 The energy and carbon dioxide tax in the housing and services sector138 5.3.2 Tax relief for installation of biofuel units as the main heating source in new houses, and for installation of energy-efficient windows in houses 140 5.3.3 Tax relief for improved energy efficiency and conversion in

public buildings 142

5.3.4 Grants for conversion in residential buildings and related premises 145

5.3.5 Property taxation 147

5.3.6 Solar heating and solar cell grants 149

5.3.7 Relationship between instruments and environmental objectives and

strategies 153

5.3.8 Interaction between instruments in the housing sector and their effects in combination with the EU emissions trading scheme 154

5.4 The transport sector 155

5.4.1 Energy and carbon dioxide tax on motor fuels 157 5.4.2 Tax exemption of biofuels for motor vehicles 162

5.4.3 Vehicle tax 164

(8)

5.4.5 Taxation of company cars and free motor fuel 170 5.4.6 Road charges for certain heavy-duty vehicles 173

5.4.7 Subsidised public transport. 173

5.4.8 Car tyre charges 175

5.4.9 The car scrapping premium 176

5.4.10 Congestion tax 177

5.4.11 Transport support 178

5.4.12 Tax reduction for alkylate petrol 179

5.4.13 Aviation tax 180

5.4.14 Environmental shipping lane dues 181

5.4.15 Grants for disposal of oil waste from ships 183

5.4.16 Environmental landing charges 184

5.4.17 Relationship between instruments and environmental objectives

and strategies 186

5.4.18 Combined effects of instruments 188

5.5 Agriculture and fisheries 189

5.5.1 Support for creation of energy forest and for cultivation

of energy crops 189

5.5.2 Grants for conservation of nature and cultural heritage, and

deciduous forestry 193

5.5.3 Nature reserves 195

5.5.4 Nature conservation agreements and biotope protection areas 198

5.5.5 Tax incentives in the forest sector 200

5.5.6 Tax on cadmium in artificial fertiliser 203

5.5.7 Tax on nitrogen in artificial fertiliser 204

5.5.8 Pesticide tax 206

5.5.9 Agriculturally-related environmental support 209

5.5.10 Energy and carbon dioxide tax 213

5.5.11 Tax relief for light heating oil ( EO1) used in agriculture and fisheries for purposes other than to operate motor vehicles in commercial operations 214 5.5.12 Tax relief on diesel use in agriculture and fisheries 215 5.5.13 Relationship between instruments and environmental objectives and

strategies 216

5.5.14 Combined effects of instruments on agriculture and fisheries 218

5.6 Other economic instruments 220

5.6.1 Environmental penalty 220

5.6.2 Landfill tax 222

(9)

5.6.4 Tax on natural gravel 227

5.6.5 Water pollution charge 229

5.6.6 Batteries charge 230

5.6.7 Radon grants 233

5.6.8 Government lake liming grants 235

5.6.9 Government funding of fisheries conservation 238

5.6.10 Relationship between the instruments and environmental objectives and

strategies 240

6 LIST OF EVALUATION REQUIREMENTS 243

General 243

Industry 243

Transport 243

Agriculture and fisheries 244

Other sectors 244

Appendix 1: Tax Agency Memorandum 5 June 2006 247

Facts 247

Time expended 247

Number of matters 248

(10)

1 Summary and conclusions

The contents of this report are based on a review of evaluations of economic in-struments in the environmental field. Particular focus has been placed on instru-ments relating to the following Swedish environmental objectives: Reduced Cli-mate Impact, Zero Eutrophication, A Non-Toxic Environment and Sustainable Forests. It is considered that these objectives will be particularly difficult to achieve within the set time limit. The analysis made is also linked to the three ac-tion strategies: (i) More efficient energy use and transport; (ii) Non-toxic and re-source-efficient cyclical systems; and (iii) Management of land, water and the built environment. The term "economic instruments" mainly refers to taxes, tax allow-ances and relief, grants and charges. Electricity certificates and the EU emissions trading scheme, which are market-based systems, are described insofar as they interact with other economic instruments. This project has been carried out over a fairly short period, and is intended to provide background material for a forthcom-ing government report on economic instruments. At the same time, instruments are also being analysed as part of the in-depth environmental objectives evaluation. Further analysis of instruments will be initiated during the forthcoming "check-point" review of Sweden's climate strategy. These projects also involve non-economic instruments, however.

The project has been carried out by the Swedish Environmental Protection Agency and the Swedish Energy Agency in consultation with the National Institute of Economic Research and the Swedish Tax Agency, following consultation with other agencies concerned with the environmental objectives, and sectoral agencies. The agencies involved have summarised the results of evaluations performed and also present their views on additional evaluations that may be necessary. We have also used existing evaluations and economic theory as a basis for drawing some general conclusions that may serve as guidance in future efforts to identify sustain-able and effective socio-economic instruments to achieve our environmental objec-tives.

Summary conclusions

x We refer to almost 200 evaluations/follow-up studies on economic in-struments in the environmental field. We have not made a comprehensive review of academic studies, however.

x Our review shows that the aim of most studies has been to monitor achievement or evaluate the effects of a given instrument, particularly in relation to its main objective, and that further consequences are some-times analysed. Comprehensive socio-economic analyses are very rare. x Many economic instruments aimed at helping to achieve the Reduced

Climate Impact objective are used. Generally speaking, multi-sectoral

taxes, such as the carbon dioxide tax, are the instruments with the great-est socio-economic potential for influencing behaviour in the intergreat-ests of

(11)

sustainability. However, the agencies consider that the potential for fu-ture deployment of taxes is limited to some extent. (See explanation later in this summary). Since grants and tax relief are generally thought to be less effective in the long term, we consider it important to include other instruments in the analysis before designing future instruments. A coher-ent forward-looking evaluation of the various economic instrumcoher-ents used in the transport sector is needed. It is also essential to take account of in-ternational aspects, such as industrial competitiveness and the EU emis-sions trading scheme. Internationally coordinated or harmonised instru-ments should be given priority.

x There are a few economic instruments aimed at specific sectors con-cerned by the Zero Eutrophication environmental objective. The NOX charge is one example of an effective instrument for the sources it cov-ers, but further use of instruments is required in many areas. The nature of the environmental problem necessitates geographical differentiation of instruments to create scope for cost-effective allocation of measures. Since there is considerable doubt about the causes of this environmental problem, action and instruments used to mitigate leaching of both phos-phorus and nitrogen should be given priority. Here too, international ef-forts are of great importance – particularly as regards other countries im-pacting on the Baltic Sea environment.

x Very few economic instruments are being used to help achieve the

Non-Toxic Environment objective, but we do not consider they are the best

means of combating chemical pollutants. This does not mean that they cannot perform an important complementary function in specific in-stances. International efforts are often of great importance. Funding for site remediation is essential if the relevant interim targets are to be met. We consider that an evaluation should be made of whether this funding is being used cost-effectively, and whether the level of funding is sufficient to achieve the relevant interim targets.

x Substantial funding has been made available under the Sustainable

For-ests objective for protection of land, which is essential to achieve this

ob-jective. Evaluations (mainly follow-up studies) have revealed that, given the current price of forest and forest land, funding will have to be in-creased to achieve the targets that have been set. We consider it neces-sary also to analyse funding forms to ensure they are as cost-effective as possible.

x The new market-based instruments systems, i.e. electricity certificates and the EU emissions trading scheme, mainly act in concert with other economic instruments to achieve the Reduced Climate Impact objective. These instruments are aimed at actors in the energy production sector and

(12)

in energy-intensive industries. The market-based instruments affect the behaviour of actors and the scope for introducing other instruments that should be used in combination with these systems.

x As a general comment, we consider that further efforts in this field should include an account of developments in the EU. In some cases EU-coordinated or harmonised instruments may be a more effective means of reducing environmental impacts as cost-effectively as possible. The EU Commission intends to instigate a number of studies over the next few years. These may bring about a discussion of economic instruments at EU level.

The agencies' proposals for further priority evaluations:

x An overall evaluation of economic instruments in the transport sector. Examples include the interplay between motor fuel taxes, the carbon di-oxide differentiated vehicle tax, and other taxes, and also ways of en-couraging the use of alternative motor fuels. The analysis should include relevant environmental objectives, action strategies and other key socie-tal goals within the sector. Potential joint EU-harmonised instruments should also be examined.

x Analysis of the effects of raising the energy tax or the carbon dioxide tax in sectors not covered by the EU emissions trading scheme. Environ-mental effects as well as the impact on corporate competitiveness should be included. It will also be necessary to examine the legal scope for this, particularly bearing in mind that the situation has changed, following the implementation of the EU emissions trading scheme.

x Examination of whether or not raising green taxes and lowering other taxes yields twin gains. If it is concluded that the current system is of du-bious benefit, then, if possible, an alternative approach should be pre-sented.

x Evaluation of whether the funding allocated for Sustainable Forests is sufficient to achieve the objectives. Evaluation of funding forms to en-sure they are as cost-effective as possible.

x Evaluation of whether the level of funding for site remediation is suffi-cient to achieve the relevant interim targets, and whether funding is being used cost-effectively.

x Evaluation of whether funding for liming of lakes and watercourses is sufficient. Evaluation of funding forms to ensure they are as cost-effective as possible.

x We also wish to point out that some of the analyses we have proposed here may be performed as part of the in-depth environmental objectives evaluation and in the forthcoming "checkpoint" interim review of Swe-den's climate strategy in 2008.

(13)

Effective long-term environmental policy

Our terms of reference state that our approach should be based on the long-term socio-economically effective use of instruments to achieve environmental objec-tives. This approach encompasses an overall view of the gains yielded by the envi-ronmental improvements (in fact an evaluation of the defined envienvi-ronmental objec-tive), and the costs to society of the instruments used to achieve the environmental objective. This is an extremely broad approach and is hardly ever adopted in a single analysis. We have taken the environmental objectives for granted in our analysis, which means that it is the cost side that must be socio-economically effec-tive in the long term. Even a comprehensive analysis of this kind involves a great deal of work, and few evaluations include comprehensive impact analyses of socio-economic effectiveness. Here, we have therefore defined three criteria in an at-tempt to describe the ability of an instrument to achieve environmental benefits effectively in the long term. These criteria are: (i) cost-effectiveness (taking the least expensive measures first); (ii) dynamic efficiency (the capacity of an instru-ment to generate technological developinstru-ment and encourage the most cost-effective solutions over time); and (iii) achievement of objectives (how well an instrument achieves a stated objective). The report uses the phrase "long-term effective use of environmental instruments" to refer to all these criteria together. In general, multi-sectoral taxes are regarded as effective instruments, whereas narrowly targeted grant schemes are considered less effective.

One step forward

The problems entailed when analysing instruments are often complex, i.e. there are many interrelationships to be described. Various delimitations are usually made. For instance, this report is largely confined to four environmental objectives,

eco-nomic instruments and existing national instruments. The report does not give a

comprehensive account of the way the economic instruments described affect and are linked to related objectives such as other energy policy goals, other environ-mental objectives and other societal goals in various sectors. This survey should therefore be seen as one step towards understanding the approach the state should adopt to achieve Sweden's environmental objectives.

Reduced Climate Impact

The economic instruments used to mitigate emissions of greenhouse gases in Swe-den are fairly numerous. Some of them span several sectors, such as energy (elec-tricity and fuels), the carbon dioxide tax and KLIMP (local climate investment programmes). Other instruments aimed at specific sectors, such as carbon dioxide differentiated vehicle tax and tax exemption for alternative motor fuels in the transport sector, conversion grants for individual heating systems, grants for con-version and improved energy efficiency in public buildings and solar heating grants in the housing sector, the NOX charge system and the PFE programme for im-proved energy efficiency in industry. There are also economic instruments that partly counteract the environmental objectives, such as company car taxation and travel allowances in the transport sector, and reduced-rate energy and carbon

(14)

dioxide taxes for industry. In addition, some instruments have a different primary purpose or a number of different purposes. Examples include vehicle tax, company car tax regulations and reduced-rate energy and carbon dioxide taxes. For instance, the aim of the PFE programme for improved energy efficiency is that the effects on electricity consumption should be equivalent to the effects that would otherwise have been achieved by the EU minimum tax (which is also reduced for companies). The ultimate effect on the Reduced Climate Impact objective depends on how the reduced energy consumed would otherwise have been produced.

LOWER AND HIGHER TAXES?

In terms of economic theory, multi-sectoral taxes such as the carbon dioxide tax, are cost-effective both in the near and the long term. This means that the tax has the potential to cause actors to take what they consider to be the cheapest measures first, while also sending a clear signal to market players, which creates an incentive for technological development (dynamic efficiency). But this is a less certain way of achieving objectives than regulation. It may be deduced from the evaluations and follow-up studies performed that the energy tax and carbon dioxide tax have had a major impact on emissions, particularly from district and individual heating systems. The studies also reveal that current tax levels have a pronounced effect on behaviour. We are therefore of the view that a further increase in the tax on heating might accelerate emission reductions and generate higher tax revenues for a limited period (since a gradual adaptation to a reduced use of fossil fuels is taking place), but would not improve the end result. One study also shows that the reduced en-ergy and carbon dioxide taxes for private industry may be cost-effective if account is taken of the risk of manufacturing operations being relocated to other countries. Although taxes are generally attractive in terms of their cost-effectiveness, the agencies consider that they offer limited additional potential for achieving the Re-duced Climate Impact objective. Aside from the fact that these taxes (on energy and carbon dioxide) already have a marked impact on certain kinds of fossil fuel use, the recently introduced emissions trading scheme also influences the way that Sweden should use the carbon dioxide tax.

Nonetheless, we consider there are some areas where it should be analysed whether the tax can be developed and its use possibly extended. One concerns those industries not covered by the EU trading system. The analysis should include the environmental effects that may be expected, as well as the effects of a higher tax on the international competitiveness of Swedish companies. There has been no evaluation analysing the interplay of various economic instruments in the transport sector. Those instruments include several taxes, such as the carbon dioxide differ-entiated vehicle tax, motor fuel tax and the tax regime for company cars. The find-ings presented in various evaluations/follow-up studies are that increased carbon dioxide differentiation of the vehicle tax and the tax regime for company cars would influence behaviour, particular if differentiation were sharp. However, there has been no analysis of ways of combining higher motor fuel taxes with these, or of the scope for devising EU-harmonised solutions so as to increase the positive im-pact on the environmental problem and increase cost-effectiveness.

(15)

REDUCE THE NUMBER OF GRANTS

The grants in use have not really been evaluated; they have been monitored. The agencies do not consider grants to be the first choice as a means of reducing cli-mate impact. If taxes are not practicable in specific instances, grants may be one of several options requiring analysis (for possible use). Any such analysis should include all possible alternatives. Cost-effectiveness and achievement of objectives to reduce emissions are generally lower where grants are used instead of taxes, for example, particularly if grant eligibility is narrowly framed. Moreover, there is a theory in economics that the best approach to dealing with phenomena causing negative external effects is to internalise the environmental cost (i.e. include it in the price), perhaps by means of a tax, not to offer grants for alternative solutions. It is also hard to retroactively evaluate the effects of grants on greenhouse gas emis-sions alongside existing taxes (particularly the taxes on energy and carbon diox-ide). This problem has been mentioned in relation to conversion grants for individ-ual heating systems and to some extent also KLIMP grants. Moreover, grants ne-cessitate central government funding, and each grant scheme requires administra-tion, which in some cases may be disproportionate to the expected results of the grant scheme. One such example is the conversion grant scheme administered by county administrative boards.

Some grants may have a narrowly defined purpose, such as grants for solar col-lectors and solar heating, where the main aim is to encourage use of this technol-ogy. Other grants may serve various purposes. One example is KLIMP, where one aim is to increase local support for action to combat climate change, and the grant for improved energy efficiency and conversion of public buildings, where an ex-press aim alongside the energy and climate objectives is to increase employment. One problem identified here is the shortage of installation technicians arising fol-lowing the introduction of numerous grants in the housing sector. It is also uncer-tain whether tax relief on the cost of installing energy-efficient windows and new biofuel boilers is cost-effective or dynamically efficient. This inference is based not on any evaluation made, however, but on interviews with builders and window manufacturers, and with the Tax Agency, which administers the tax relief.

One final conclusion is that the scope for further use of economic instruments

to achieve Reduced Climate Impact is limited in some respects (assuming that they must be effective in the long term). It is therefore essential that future evaluations include the other instruments available. For instance, it may be useful in the hous-ing sector to ascertain how standards, buildhous-ing regulations and information can serve as a complement to the present tax regime.

(16)

Zero Eutrophication

SEVERAL ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS CONTROLLING NITROGEN EMISSIONS

Although the tax on nitrogen has had a limited impact on the sale of artificial fertil-isers, its indirect effects have been greater, in that the tax has funded environmental compensation payments, which have reduced leaching of nitrogen as well as phos-phorus. The NOx charge scheme for power plants is a cost-effective instrument and a complement to emission conditions set in operating permits. The charge scheme has yielded a quicker and cheaper reduction in emissions than could have been achieved using the more static instrument of emission conditions alone.

EU agricultural support has done much to create agricultural surpluses, a situa-tion which exacerbates nutrient leaching from agriculture. An analysis of the ef-fects of direct support (cash support based on area of cultivated land or livestock numbers) and environmental compensation (e.g. support for pasture land, organic production and wetlands) shows that positive and negative environmental impacts are often linked, and that grants may even counteract each other. Following the recent reform of EU agricultural support, many of these effects are expected to disappear, but it is too early to evaluate the results. The projected effects of the EU agricultural reform in 2003, implemented in Sweden in 2005, indicate a reduction in nitrogen leaching.

NEW OPPORTUNITIES OFFERED BY THE IMPLEMENTATION OF THE WATER FRAMEWORK DIRECTIVE

The Swedish implementation of the EU Water Framework Directive (WFD) will provide additional means of safeguarding water quality. Although it only concerns surface water, groundwater and coastal areas, measures taken within catchments usually also benefit the marine environment. The WFD emphasises the use of pric-ing policies and enshrines the "polluter pays" principle and the aim of achievpric-ing the objectives cost-effectively. The WFD recommends instruments that are

self-financing as well as cost-effective, which suggests there is scope for greater use of economic instruments in particular, since only they can meet these criteria.

NEED FOR GREATER USE OF INSTRUMENTS

First and foremost, there is great potential for developing economic instruments designed to reduce leaching of phosphorus, since economic instruments in Sweden to date have largely focused on reducing the nitrogen load. Improved management of farmyard manure is considered to offer great potential for reducing phosphorus and nitrogen emissions at a low cost. This kind of action will require an instrument that creates financial incentives for farmers to make the necessary investments so that farmyard manure can be stored until it can be spread at the right time. An evaluation of whether economic instruments could help to improve treatment at sewage treatment plants is also desirable.

(17)

To reduce emissions of nitrogen oxides, perhaps the greatest development po-tential concerns emissions of nitrogen oxides from shipping, since other forms of transport will be covered by the new EC directive imposing tighter standards on exhaust emissions from heavy duty vehicles. However, there is a need for interna-tional instruments in this area, since shipping faces internainterna-tional competition, which limits the effect of national instruments.

In general, it may be said that since instruments designed to achieve action in Sweden have a limited impact on eutrophication in the Baltic Sea, there is a need to create international instruments also impacting on emissions from other countries polluting the Baltic Sea. And, to maintain our credibility in international environ-mental cooperation, Sweden should also take additional measures.

GEOGRAPHICAL DIFFERENTIATION

Although there are now quite a number of economic instruments aimed at nitrogen emissions, there is a need to redesign them to better reflect their actual impact on eutrophication by means of geographical differentiation. Unfortunately, at present there is both considerable doubt and considerable disagreement about transport of nutrients from source to receiving water body, and their effects on the water body.

A Non-Toxic Environment

ECONOMIC INSTRUMENTS SECOND A SECOND BEST SOLUTION

One study analysing whether economic instruments can be used more to achieve the Non-Toxic Environment objective has said that taxation of chemicals use is mainly justified by the existence of negative external effects along the production chain. The report also says that these diffuse effects are difficult to control directly, and it may instead therefore be advisable to tax use or manufacture of the chemi-cals causing the problems. But doubt about the marginal cost of reducing chemichemi-cals use, combined with an often steeply rising marginal damage effect above a critical level, means that quantitative controls (or even bans) may be a more effective means of limiting chemicals use than taxes. Hence, taxes on chemicals do not offer any general solutions to environmental problems associated with the Non-Toxic Environment objective; their effectiveness relative to other instruments must be assessed on its merits in each case. This does not prevent economic instruments from serving as an important complement in certain cases.

Since product streams are often international, it is important that economic in-struments in this field are supported by international organisations, and do not conflict with international agreements.

RESULTS FROM ONGOING STUDY PENDING

There is an ongoing study initiated by the National Chemicals Inspectorate aiming to identify the areas of chemicals manufacture and use for which economic instru-ments may be appropriate, either to reinforce existing instruinstru-ments in the form of laws and regulations, or for substances or areas in which there are currently no

(18)

instruments. We consider that we should wait until the results of that study are published before drawing any definite conclusions about the way economic instru-ments can be used to help achieve the Non-Toxic Environment objective.

FUNDING IMPORTANT BUT IN NEED OF EVALUATION

The funding that has been made available for site remediation is of great impor-tance in achieving one of the difficult environmental objectives (Non-Toxic Envi-ronment), besides being a very large sum of money.

Funding of site remediation and clean-up activities in general have been under-going a phase of rapid expansion and development. This notwithstanding, it is considered that the relevant interim target will be hard to achieve on the basis of current available funding. We therefore consider it a priority to evaluate the system so as to assess the amount of funding required to achieve the relevant interim tar-gets and whether this can be done more cost-effectively.

Sustainable Forests

There are few specifically environment-related economic instruments aimed at achieving the Sustainable Forests objective. However, tax policy exerts a powerful influence over forest owners and their forests. Hence, from an environmental ob-jective viewpoint, it is essential to analyse tax effects and consider instruments that promote, or at least do not hamper, achievement of the objective.

Follow-up studies have shown that, given the current price of forest and forest land, the funding available for formal forest protection must be increased if the stated objectives are to be achieved.

Current capital gains taxation regulations hinder the creation of nature re-serves. These regulations should be reviewed with a view to encouraging and fa-cilitating the creation of nature reserves. A change in the right to treat income

re-ceived under nature conservation agreements in accordance with accrual account-ing principles, which is one of the major obstacles to concludaccount-ing agreements of this

kind, is also considered a priority.

Although budget appropriations for purchase of land and payment of compen-sation for land-use restrictions and land management have risen sharply in recent years, funding is considered to be inadequate. Monitoring and evaluation of the land management appropriation needs to be developed and improved. In our opin-ion, there is an urgent need to evaluate the environmental effects of these appro-priations, to determine whether they are cost-effective instruments.

The Swedish Agency for Public Management has been instructed by the Gov-ernment to evaluate existing nature conservation instruments (nature reserves, bio-tope protection areas and nature conservation agreements) and their long-term cost-effectiveness, and also how state forests can be used to help achieve the entire Sustainable Forests objective. The Agency's report is to be submitted by 30 Sep-tember 2007.

(19)

Economic instruments and the three action strategies

We have also been asked to relate our evaluations of the economic instruments to the three defined action strategies. Our general conclusions on economic instru-ments are not altered when they are described in terms of the "intersection" in vari-ous strategies. All three strategies involve the use of economic instruments to achieve their ends. Instruments are most frequently used in the strategies for More Efficient Energy use and Transport and least frequent in Non-toxic and Resource-efficient Cyclical Systems. One aim in developing the strategies is to identify in-struments serving several environmental objectives and covering many measures and sectors. The energy tax, carbon dioxide tax, sulphur tax and, to some extent, KLIMP grants, are examples of such economic instruments. The taxes in particular also meet the long-term effectiveness criteria. The international perspective and improving energy efficiency are of particular importance to the strategy for More Efficient Energy use and Transport and the strategy for Non-toxic and Resource-efficient Cyclical Systems. In theoretical terms, general use of energy taxes is con-sidered to be a cost-effective means of improving energy efficiency. This has also been confirmed by interviews with builders, window manufacturers and in a num-ber of energy-intensive industries. High energy prices are cited as the single most important reason for improving energy efficiency. Instruments leading to more efficient use of electricity, e.g. the electricity consumption tax and the PFE pro-gramme for improved energy efficiency, are fairly complicated to evaluate from an environmental objectives perspective. One problem is that the environmental effect materialises at the production stage, rather than the consumption stage. Moreover, electricity is produced in a Nordic market, which means that the effect of measures in Sweden on emissions may occur in other countries.

OBVIOUS GOAL CONFLICTS

In the agencies' view, it may be important when developing strategies to consider the attitude to be adopted towards instruments/measures where there are potential goal conflicts. In general, it may be said that goal conflicts are seldom examined in the studies we have read. One example of a goal conflict is increased use of ethanol as a motor fuel (largely due to various economic instruments such as exemption from energy tax, lower taxation of company cars, local incentives such as free parking etc), and a desire to increase the rate of improvements in energy efficiency. The use of ethanol (based on renewable energy sources) reduces greenhouse gas emissions from the transport sector, but also reduces energy efficiency, since con-verting solid biomass into liquid ethanol requires more energy than does the manu-facture of petrol and diesel. This goal conflict in the strategy for More Efficient Energy use and Transport is highlighted because increased use of renewable fuels and energy efficiency are both important elements of the strategy. Another goal conflict may be a sharp increase in use of biofuels (encouraged by economic in-struments, among other things) and the Sustainable Forests and Rich Diversity of Plant and Animal Life objectives. If biomass use does increase sharply, the effect of this on these other environmental objectives should be made clear. In addition, new production of electricity from renewable sources may conflict with some of

(20)

the environmental objectives falling within the framework of the strategy for Man-agement of Land, Water and the Built Environment. Building a power plant does not always intrude and impact on the surrounding environment, however.

Coordination with the electricity certificate scheme and the EU emis-sions trading scheme

The EU emissions trading scheme forms part of the joint EU climate strategy and was introduced as a harmonised instrument in 2005. The system covers the energy production sector and most energy-intensive industries, and is also linked to global trade in that some emissions can be covered by credits under the project-based mechanisms. It has therefore become important to take account of the effects of this system in analyses of instruments covering Swedish emissions in the trading sectors. In particular, the system operates together with the carbon dioxide tax and the electricity certificate scheme. The latter was introduced primarily as an incen-tive for electricity production from renewable energy sources, thereby helping to secure energy supply in the EU. However, the system has clear effects on the envi-ronmental objectives, since it favours renewable energy production over natural gas-based electricity production, for example. The PFE programme for improved energy efficiency in industry also acts together with these systems. Measures taken under PFE and the EU emissions trading scheme can complement each other. It is not possible to make a final assessment of the effects of PFE, as the programme has not yet been evaluated.

Several studies have concluded that, as a matter of principle, the carbon dioxide tax should be abolished in the sectors covered by the EU emissions trading scheme. The tax and the trading system act in the same way and duplicate instruments are inefficient. However, one study points out that the carbon dioxide tax should re-main for parts of the energy production sector, i.e. the district heating sector, so as not to forfeit progress already made in achieving a higher proportion of biofuels used in production. The agencies also wish to highlight another consequence of the EU trading system. In the near term (during the current allocation period for emis-sion allowances) the effects on total EU emisemis-sions of lower electricity consumption (effects of the consumption tax on electricity and conversion grants for buildings heated by electricity) or a greater proportion of renewable electricity production (the electricity certificate scheme) remain unchanged. This is because lower emis-sions from the Nordic electricity system at the same time allow higher emisemis-sions in another EU country under the EU emissions trading scheme. Eventually, when new trading periods begin, lower emissions resulting from these instruments may affect the scope for future allocation of emission allowances.

Examine the scope for more joint EU instruments

Lastly, we wish to emphasise the importance of also examining the scope for fur-ther development of joint EU instruments. The Commission will be presenting a green paper on market-based instruments in early 2007. The European Environ-ment Bureau has proposed a programme of tax reforms using the "open coordina-tion" method. The new sustainability strategy adopted at the EU summit in June

(21)

2006 urges member states to continue the shift towards green taxation. The Com-mission will be presenting a report in 2007 on current systems used by member states. In 2008 the Commission will be presenting a report containing proposals on ways of phasing out the most environmentally harmful subsidies. Environmental problems associated with Reduced Climate Impact, the strategy for More Efficient Energy use and Transport, the Zero Eutrophication, Non-Toxic Environment objec-tives, and the strategy for Non-toxic and Resource-efficient Cyclical Systems are not confined by national boundaries. Joint EU economic instruments should there-fore be included in the analysis of the Sweden's approach to developing economic instruments to achieve the stated environmental objectives. It may be added that trade and industry have demanded more international harmonisation and coordina-tion, since many companies make and sell their products in an international market. Developments in the R&D field (both in the private sector and the academic world) also often take place in an international arena.

A final coherent strategy must also consider other instruments

A comparison with other instruments must also be made to determine whether an economic instrument is the most effective one. Moreover, instruments often act in concert. For instance, the NOx system operates in parallel with operating permit application procedures, which means that all existing and potential instruments should be analysed in parallel to evaluate their effects and potential.

Defining the terms used in future evaluations

Finally, we wish to refer back to our introductory comments on various concepts and definitions describing the socio-economic effectiveness of our approach to achieving the environmental objectives. Going forward, it is essential that the terms used are defined clearly and used consistently. A comprehensive socio-economic analysis should also analyse and evaluate the definitions of the objectives them-selves. The socio-economic impact analysis should also examine the consequences for other societal objectives. We would here like to stress that adverse effects on other societal objectives may sometimes be a reason to modify the instrument, but not in all cases. Other government measures can also be used to alleviate the nega-tive effects of the instrument.

(22)

Summary of the need to evaluate economic instruments

Table 1 Has the instrument been sufficiently evaluated and is it considered to be effective in the long run? A summary of the instruments surveyed.

Instrument Has the

instru-ment been suffi-ciently evalu-ated? Is the instrument a long-term effective means of furthering environmental inter-ests (based on the criteria of cost-effectiveness, dy-namic efficiency and achievement of objec-tives)?

Main objective(s)

Multi-sectoral

General comments on energy and carbon dioxide taxes

Yes, except for re-duced-rate taxes for industry outside the EU emissions trading scheme

Yes, tax reductions may be justified for trade and industry policy reasons.

Reduced Climate Impact. Fiscal.

Energy system transition.

Sulphur tax Essentially yes, but

the effect of lowering the tax exemption limit needs to be examined.

Yes. Zero Eutrophication.

Natural Acidification Only. Clean Air.

KLIMP (local climate investment pro-grammes

Yes. Probably not, but fairly effectively for a grant system, owing to broad coverage and flexible choice of measures.

Reduced Climate Impact. Energy system transition.

Grants for market launch of energy-efficient technologies

No. More analysis is needed.

With the right design, the instrument is thought to have the potential to com-plement other instruments.

Energy system transition.

Manufacturing industry and energy production

Financial support for wind power, in-cluding environmental bonus

No, no evaluations made.

No. Energy system transition.

Programme for Improved Energy Effi-ciency (PFE)

No. Doubtful, although the

effects of this instrument interact positively with other economic instru-ments.

Trade and industry policy. Energy system transition.

Property tax on wind power and hydro-power

Not in terms of its environmental im-pact.

Unclear. Fiscal.

Nuclear power output tax Not in terms of its environmental im-pact.

Unclear. Fiscal. Energy system transition.

NOx charge Yes Yes, for sources included. Zero Eutrophication.

Natural Acidification Only.

(23)

Instrument Has the instru-ment been suffi-ciently evalu-ated? Is the instrument a long-term effective means of furthering environmental inter-ests (based on the criteria of cost-effectiveness, dy-namic efficiency and achievement of objec-tives)?

Main objective(s)

Housing and services etc. Tax relief for installation of biofuel unit serving as main heating source in new houses and for installation of energy-efficient windows in existing houses.

No. No. Narrow focus. Reduced Climate Impact.

Energy system transition.

Grants for improved energy efficiency and conversion in public buildings (OFFROT).

No. The Board of Housing, Building and Planning pre-sented a plan for monitoring and evaluation of these grants in June 2005.

No. May have brought measures forward, but they are often profitable even without grants.

Reduced Climate Impact. Energy system transition. Increased employment.

Conversion grants for homes and re-lated premises

No. The Board of Housing, Building and Planning pre-sented a plan for monitoring and evaluation of these grants in June 2005.

No. May have brought measures forward, but they are often profitable even without grants.

Reduced Climate Impact. Energy system transition.

Property taxation Not in terms of its environmental im-pact.

Possibly counterproduc-tive, but probably limited.

Fiscal.

Solar heating and solar panel grants (solar panel grants under OFFROT)

No, monitored, if anything.

No. The main aim is to encourage the use of a given technology. The design of the scheme is in need of review.

Energy system transition.

Transport sector

Motor fuel tax Yes. Yes. The effect on other

societal goals may limit the scope for using motor fuel tax.

Fiscal.

Reduced Climate Impact. + other external effects (noise, road wear etc). Tax exemption for biofuels No. Unclear. Its effect alone

and with other instruments needs to be examined.

Reduced Climate Impact. Energy system transition.

Vehicle tax No. Probably not. Its effect in

conjunction with other instruments in the sector needs to be analysed.

Fiscal.

Reduced Climate Impact.

Environmental classification of motor fuels and differential taxes

Yes. Yes. Natural Acidification Only

Clean Air

Zero Eutrophication. Non-Toxic Environment.

(24)

Instrument Has the instru-ment been suffi-ciently evalu-ated? Is the instrument a long-term effective means of furthering environmental inter-ests (based on the criteria of cost-effectiveness, dy-namic efficiency and achievement of objec-tives)?

Main objective(s)

Taxation of company cars and free motor fuel

No. Counterproductive. Amended regulations

combined with other eco-nomic instruments in the transport sector should be analysed.

Fiscal.

Clean Air, Natural Acidifi-cation Only, Reduced Climate Impact. (Amended regulations) Road charges for certain types of

heavy-duty vehicles No. No. Different main pur-pose. Effects combined with other economic in-struments in the sector should be analysed.

Fiscal.

Acidification, Clean Air. (Differentiation)

Subsidised public transport. Yes. Doubtful. Other aspects need to be taken into account, however.

Several traffic policy objectives

Reduced Climate Impact. Energy system transition.

Car-scrapping premium Yes. Not in terms of

encourag-ing people to scrap old vehicles. Does encourage people to take their scrap vehicles to scrap yards.

Non-Toxic Environment. Natural Acidification Only. Zero Eutrophication. Clean Air.

Congestion tax (trial in Stockholm) Yes. Yes. Clean Air.

Fiscal.

Reduced Climate Impact.

Transport funding Yes. Probably marginal effect. Regional policy.

Lower tax on alkylate petrol No. Unclear. More incentives needed.

Non-Toxic Environment.

Aviation tax No. No. Does not influence

technical development. Global markets entail a risk of carbon dioxide "leak-age".

Reduced Climate Impact. Fiscal.

Environmental shipping lane dues No. No. Increased use of inter-nationally harmonised instruments needed.

Zero Eutrophication. Natural Acidification Only. Clean Air.

Environmental landing fees Yes. No. Increased use of inter-nationally harmonised instruments needed.

Zero Eutrophication. Natural Acidification Only. Clean Air.

Grants for disposal of oil waste from ships

No evaluations made.

No. Essentially regulation. Very few grant applications received.

Balanced Marine Envi-ronment.

Agriculture, forestry, fisheries

Grants for planting of energy forest and cultivation of energy crops

Yes (white paper under preparation)

No. Design of the scheme may be in need of review.

Reduced Climate Impact. Energy system transition.

(25)

Instrument Has the instru-ment been suffi-ciently evaluated?

Is the instrument a long-term effective means of furthering environmental interests (based on the criteria of cost-effectiveness, dy-namic efficiency and achievement of objec-tives)?

Main objective(s)

Grants for conservation of natural and cultural heritage, and management of broad-leaved deciduous woodland

No, but not a priority. Difficult to say. But there has been a positive effect on natural and cultural assets in woodland.

Sustainable Forests.

Tax incentives in the forest sector Yes. Counterproductive: Regu-lations in need of review.

General taxation princi-ples.

Sustainable Forests. Purchases, compensation for land-use

restrictions and management of forest land

No. Environmental effect and level of funding should be evaluated.

Unclear. Sustainable Forests.

Tax on cadmium in artificial fertiliser Yes. Yes, nationally speaking Non-Toxic Environment. Tax on nitrogen in artificial fertiliser Yes. No: Geographical

differen-tiation desirable.

Zero Eutrophication.

Pesticide tax Yes. Limited effect Non-Toxic Environment.

Agricultural environmental compensa-tion

No, needed continu-ously.

Unclear, acts for and against.

Varied Agricultural Land-scape.

CAP. Tax relief on light heating oil ( EO1)

used in agriculture and forestry for purposes other than operating motor vehicles

No. Counterproductive. Trade and industry policy.

Tax relief on use of diesel in agriculture, forestry and fisheries

No, but not a priority. Counterproductive. Trade and industry policy.

Other economic instruments

Landfill tax Yes. Yes (may require

differen-tiation).

Reduced Climate Impact. Good Built Environment. EU waste strategy. Funding of site remediation No, effectiveness and

funding level should be evaluated.

Unclear. Non-Toxic Environment.

Good Quality Groundwa-ter.

Tax on natural gravel Yes. Limited contribution – main

impact via permit applica-tion procedure.

Good Built Environment.

Water pollution charge Yes. Unclear link but probably

prevents emissions.

Balanced Marine Envi-ronment.

Batteries charge No, the charge

should be evaluated.

Unclear. Non-Toxic Environment.

Radon grants Yes. Can probably be made

more effective. Greater incentive needed.

Good Built Environment.

Government grants for liming of lakes No, effectiveness and funding level need evaluating.

Unclear. Natural Acidification Only.

Government funding of fisheries con-servation measures

No, better monitoring needed.

Unclear. Flourishing Lakes and

(26)

2 Background

In their respective letters of instruction for 2006, the Swedish Energy Agency and the Swedish EPA were given the following assignment by the Government:

The Swedish Environmental Protection Agency and the Swedish Energy Agency in consultation with the National Institute of Economic Research and the Swedish Tax Agency, following consultation with other agencies concerned with the environ-mental objectives, and sectoral agencies, are instructed to prepare a summary of existing knowledge on the effects of economic instruments in relation to Sweden's environmental objectives. Where there are no evaluations of environmentally-related economic instruments, or where the quality of evaluations is inadequate, new evaluations are to be made. The scope of those evaluations is to be agreed with the Government Offices. The analysis made is also linked to the three action strategies: (i) More efficient energy use and transport; (ii) Non-toxic and resource-efficient cyclical systems; and (iii) Management of land, water and the built envi-ronment. The report should focus on the long-term socio-economically effective use of instruments to achieve environmental objectives. The potential synergies created by various economic instruments in relation to one ore more environmental quality objectives are to be taken into account, as are any counter-effects. The analysis should therefore be linked to the three action strategies: (i) More efficient energy use and transport; (ii) Non-toxic and resource-efficient cyclical systems; and (iii) Management of land, water and the built environment.

The report should focus particularly on the environmental quality objectives and interim targets that will be difficult or very difficult to achieve within a genera-tion according to the Environmental Objectives Bill (2004/05:150). For the pur-poses of this report "economic instruments in the environmental field" means taxes, including relief, allowances, rebates and refunds, charges and direct grants. The agencies involved should describe the way these instruments operate in conjunc-tion with emissions trading and electricity certificates. The report should also cover taxes and charges whose primary function is to generate revenue, but that have an impact on the environment and may therefore counteract the effects of other instruments. The agencies may divide tasks between themselves on the basis of their areas of expertise and responsibility. This report is the first of two parts of a study that will form part of the in-depth evaluation in 2008. It is also a comple-ment to the efforts being made by the agencies concerned by environcomple-mental objec-tives to propose measures, including economic instruments, under their respective objectives. The "Checkpoint 2008" review of Sweden's climate strategy should particularly be taken into account. The report must be submitted by 1 October 2006.

Following further discussions with the Ministry of the Environment, it was decided that the main emphasis of the report would be a survey and review of evaluations of existing environmental economic instruments, which includes identifying areas where new evaluations are needed. Overall conclusions have also been drawn on

(27)

the basis of the evaluations reviewed. No new evaluations have been made as part of this report.

(28)

3 Introduction

3.1 Purpose, method and scope

The main purpose of the report is to facilitate the work of the commission due to be appointed in autumn 2006, whose task will be to submit proposals for new or modified economic instruments with a view to achieving the environmental objec-tives.

The report also constitutes background material for the in-depth evaluation of the environmental objectives in 2008 and the "Checkpoint" review of the "Reduced Climate Impact" objective, also in 2008. The report is largely based on existing evaluations (as well as two interview studies on recently introduced instruments, performed at the instigation of the Swedish Energy Agency. The project team has summarised relevant evaluations and made overall conclusions for each instrument.

The agencies involved have had the opportunity to comment on the project in two consultative phases: (i) on the scope of the instrument and the evaluations considered to be relevant; and (ii) on the report as a whole. The agencies involved have been assumed to be those having responsibility for an objective or a sector relating to achievement of the Swedish environmental objectives. This project has been carried out in fairly close cooperation with the National Institute of Economic Research and the Swedish Tax Agency. These agencies have commented on work-ing material and also written some sections of this report.

The definition of economic instruments and hence how we have delimited this project, is described in section 3.5. The report deals with existing (i.e. not abol-ished/or not yet introduced) national (i.e. imposed by central government) Swedish economic instruments in the environmental field. Some borderline cases are exam-ined where considered relevant, particularly instruments involving large sums of money and playing a central role in achievement of environmental objectives, or those clearly counteracting environmentally-related economic instruments.

Overall conclusions have been drawn with regard to the environmental objec-tives regarded as being of the highest priority: the four environmental objecobjec-tives considered in 2005 to be very difficult to achieve by the set deadline (Reduced Climate Impact, A Non-Toxic Environment, Zero Eutrophication and Sustainable Forests), as well as the three action strategies for achieving the environmental ob-jectives: (i) More efficient energy use and transport; (ii) Non-toxic and resource-efficient cyclical systems; and (iii) Management of land, water and the built envi-ronment.

Changes will also have to be made in our approach to achieving the other envi-ronmental objectives. Hence, there may very well be good reason for using eco-nomic instruments to achieve these objectives and interim targets. In light of our terms of reference, and to enable us to maintain some sort of uniform focus in the project, overall conclusions have not been drawn for those other objectives and interim targets. Some of them are presented in outline in chapter 2.3.

(29)

3.2 Structure of the report

Chapter 3 describes the background, purpose and scope of the report.

Environ-mental objectives and their achievement, strategies and other societal goals are presented. The chapter also contains an introductory explanation of what is meant by economic instruments, and quality criteria for assessing the effectiveness of a given instrument.

Chapter 4 presents overall conclusions for the four priority environmental

objec-tives considered in the report. These conclusions are based on the survey of instru-ments. Overall conclusions are likewise drawn for the three action strategies in this chapter.

Chapter 5 presents the sector-by-sector survey of instruments that has been carried

out. The history and purpose of each instrument are presented, along with evalua-tions, followed by an overall assessment of the extent to which the instrument has been evaluated and comments on its effectiveness.

3.3 Environmental objectives and other

societal goals

Environmental protection and policy in Sweden are currently based on 16 envi-ronmental objectives (see Table 2).

There are a number of interim targets under each objective (72 in total), which are also listed in the table. There were originally 15 environmental objectives, dat-ing back to April 1999. The environmental objectives and interim targets were revised in November 2005: several interim targets were altered, some were modi-fied, some were added, and an entirely new environmental objective was adopted. The in-depth evaluation in 2008 will propose new and modified interim targets, at least for those with a 2010 deadline.

Table 2 Sweden's 16 environmental objectives and interim targets (objectives given prior-ity in this report are shaded)

Reduced Climate Impact Reduced emissions of greenhouse gases (2008 - 2012)

Clean Air Concentration of sulphur dioxide (2005)

Concentration of nitrogen dioxide (2010) Concentration of ground-level ozone (2010) Emissions of VOCs (2010)

Concentration of particles (2010) Concentration of benso(a)pyrene (2015) Natural Acidification Only Fewer acidified water bodies (2010)

Trend reversal for soil acidification (2010) Reduced sulphur emissions (2010) Reduced nitrogen emissions (2010)

A Non-Toxic Environment Data on the health and environmental properties of chemical substances (2010/2020)

(30)

(2010)

Phase-out of hazardous substances (2007/2010) Ongoing reduction of health and environmental risks associated with chemicals (2010)

Guideline values for environmental quality (2010) Surveys of contaminated sites completed (2010) Site remediation areas (2005-2010)/2050 Dioxins in food (2010)

Exposure to cadmium (2015)

A Protective Ozone Layer Emissions of ozone depleting substances (2010) A Safe Radiation Environment Emissions of radioactive substances (2010)

Skin cancer caused by UV-radiation (2020) Risks associated with electromagnetic fields (ongo-ing)

Zero Eutrophication Reduced emissions of phosphorus compounds (2010)

Reduced emissions of nitrogen compounds to the sea (2010)

Reduced emissions of ammonia (2010)

Reduced emissions of nitrogen oxides to air (2010) Flourishing Lakes and Streams Action programme for natural habitats and cultural

heritage (2005/2010)

Action programme for restoration of rivers and streams (2005/2010)

Water supply plans (2009)

Release of animals and plants living in aquatic habitats (2005)

Action programme for endangered species and fish stocks (2005)

Good Quality Groundwater Protection of geological formations (2010) Impact of changes in water table (2010) Groundwater quality standards (2010) A Balanced Marine Environment,

Flour-ishing Coastal Areas and Archipelagos

Protection of marine environments, coastal areas and archipelagos (2005/2006/2010)

Strategy for cultural heritage and cultivated land-scapes in coastal areas and archipelagos (2005) Action programmes for endangered marine species and fish stocks (2005)

Reduction in bycatches (2010) Adjustment of fishing quotas (2008) Disturbance caused by boat traffic (2010) Discharges from ships (2010)

Thriving Wetlands Protection and management strategy (2005) Long-term wetland protection (2010) Forest roads and wetlands (2006)

Creation and restoration of wetlands (2010) Action programmes for endangered species (2005) Sustainable Forests Long-term protection of forest land (2010)

Greater biodiversity (2010)

Protection of cultural heritage (2010)

Action programmes for endangered species (2005) A Varied Agricultural Landscape Management of meadow and pasture land (2010)

Conservation and creation of small-scale habitats on farmland (2005)

Management of culturally important landscape features (2010)

Genetic resources of livestock and cultivated plants (2010)

Action programmes for endangered species (2006) Farm buildings (2005)

A Magnificent Mountain Landscape Reduce damage to soil and vegetation (2010) Reduce noise in mountain areas (2010/2015)

(31)

Protection of areas rich in natural assets and cultural heritage (2010)

Action programmes for endangered species (2005) A Good Built Environment Planning documentation (2010)

Built environments of value in terms of their cultural heritage (2010)

Noise (2010)

Gravel extraction (2010)

Reduction in waste quantities (2005/2010/2015) Energy use in buildings (2010)

Good quality indoor environment (2010/2015/2020) A Rich Diversity of Plant and Animal Life Halted loss of biodiversity (2010)

Lower percentage of endangered species (2015) Sustainable hunting (2007/2010)

Source: Environmental Objectives Council (2006a).

The environmental objectives are a grouping of political objectives for society among many others laid down in Sweden. The various societal goals impact on each other, and may in some cases counteract one another. For this reason it is essential that other policy areas and societal goals are also borne in mind when evaluating instruments affecting the environmental objectives. This report de-scribes other societal goals where they have an obvious connection to a given in-strument, depending on whether they fall within the scope of existing evaluations. This report does not describe these other goals in full, however. Figure 1 illustrates the environment in which instruments operate.

Increased wealth and welfare

Climate Environ-ment Energy Industry Distribution Industrial competitiveness Housing Health Defence Traffic Growth Employment Consumer Transport Forest Fiscal Agriculture Research

Industry transitionEnergy TransportHouseholds(housing) Services

Agriculture Forestry Municipalities Agencies National legislation Inter-national agreements Directives White cer-tificates Energy-declarations Extended trading-scheme Heating Certifcates Kilometre tax Planning, building and housing act

Environ-mental code Emissions

trading CO2 tax LTA

Electricity certificates Energy Tax KLIMP Sulphur Tax NOX charge Waste Tax Environ- mental-bonus Investment grants Conversion grants Labelling Certif. Energy Advice Vehicle Tax Information

Figure 1 Instruments, their interplay with other instruments and various societal goals and the way they target different actors.

(32)

3.4 Instruments to achieve the objectives

The following questions must be asked continuously when working to achieve the various environmental objectives and when developing the various strategies in-volved:

x Are there any central government instruments and, if so, how powerful are they?

x What kinds of instrument have the greatest impact on behaviour?

This survey of instruments in use focuses on economic instruments. The market-based trading schemes are not included, but the way other economic instruments interact with the market-based schemes should be described. Table 3 outlines the main categories of instruments that exist.

Table 3 Main types of instrument

Economic Regulation Information Research

x Taxes x Tax relief x Charges x Grants x Subsidies x Deposit schemes x Emissions trading x Certificate trading x Emission guideline values x Requirements for fuel choice and energy efficiency x Long-term agree-ments x Environmental clas-sification x Information x Advisory x Education/training x Lobbying/influencing public opinion x Research x Development x Demonstration x (Technology procurement)

Source: Swedish Energy Agency and Swedish EPA (2004b) (somewhat modified).

Economic instruments. According to the OECD, a characteristic feature of

eco-nomic instruments is that they affect the cost and benefit of choices made by those concerned. This may be seen as a manifestation of the "polluter pays" principle. Economic instruments are environmental taxes and environmental charges, trans-ferable emission allowances, deposit schemes, grants and subsidies. When a tax or charge is linked directly to an environmental problem, people are encouraged to use resources in a less environmental burdensome way. A variant of environmental taxes is to environmentally differentiate product taxes that were originally intended simply to generate revenue so as to help achieve an environmental objective with-out increasing the overall tax burden. Transferable emission allowances are a com-bination of regulation and economic instrument. The right to emit a substance is regulated in the form of a "guideline value" at system level, and transferable emis-sions rights are issued at the same time. These can be sold in a market. The result (i.e. the action taken) of the tax or emission right is essentially the same. Emission reductions occur when adaptive measures that are cheaper than the cost of the tax or the emission allowance are carried out.

Figure

Table 1 Has the instrument been sufficiently evaluated and is it considered to be effective  in the long run? A summary of the instruments surveyed
Table 2 Sweden's 16 environmental objectives and interim targets (objectives given prior- prior-ity in this report are shaded)
Figure 1 Instruments, their interplay with other instruments and various societal goals and the way  they target different actors
Table 3 Main types of instrument
+7

References

Related documents

Skulle utskicken från bolag till influencers anses vara reklamgåvor, skulle följaktligen bolagen få göra avdrag för de utgifter som uppstår i samband med

Eleverna ges även stöttor då frågor ställs som kan underlätta för deras tolkning då läraren till exempel frågar varför flickan i boken får ett straff.. Då detta

Multi- variate proteomic analysis of the cerebrospinal fluid of patients with peripheral neuropathic pain and healthy controls – a hypothesis- generating pilot study.. Wolfe F,

Another coordinator whose network was financed by the Swedish Energy Agency pointed out anyway that the fee could force the companies to implement the energy efficiency

Moreover, given that many environmental problems are ‘imported’ through the supply chain (e.g. Elkington, 1994), all case companies scrutinize their suppliers and subcontractors

The mechanism scheme is interwoven with a framework drawing on the natural-resource-based view to investigate the third area of interest: how strategies for

Different VAs concerning groundwater, lakes, watercourses and wetlands are in place in Denmark. The management plan consists of several wetland projects in the

This chapter combines the identified development in the use of economic instruments in the Nordic countries from the 1990’s to 2017 with the development in selected indicators of