• No results found

EXAMENSARBETEN I MATEMATIK MATEMATISKA INSTITUTIONEN, STOCKHOLMS UNIVERSITET

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "EXAMENSARBETEN I MATEMATIK MATEMATISKA INSTITUTIONEN, STOCKHOLMS UNIVERSITET"

Copied!
44
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

EXAMENSARBETEN I MATEMATIK

MATEMATISKA INSTITUTIONEN, STOCKHOLMS UNIVERSITET

Optimal Cash Management

av

Elin Oxenhielm

2005 - No 7

(2)
(3)

Optimal Cash Management

Elin Oxenhielm

Examensarbete i matematik 10 po¨ang Handledare: Jan-Erik Bj¨ork

2005

(4)
(5)

Abstract

We study the problem of optimising the flow of cash in a large company when the cash reserve is assumed to follow a jump-diffusion process. This means that we have a Brownian motion to model ordinary fluctuations and a Poisson process to model large fluctuations, jumps, that occur due to rare unpredictable events such as wars or natural disasters. We derive the solution to this stochastic optimal control problem for both a pure diffusion model and a jump-diffusion model. The solution will be of "bang-bang" type, i.e. there exists a "switch point" at which it is optimal to change strategy. By numerical studies we analyse the switch point's qualitative properties, as well as the value of all cash that we take out over time as a function of the initial cash level. We also interpret this problem as the problem of deciding how much to supply of a specific commodity (we study the U.S. crude oil price in detail) based on an observed price, maximising the total supplied amount over time constraint to a maximum production capacity.

(6)

Contents

1 Introduction 1

1.1 The Problem 1

1.2 Objective 2

1.3 Organisation of the Thesis 3

2 Preliminaries 4

2.1 Stochastic Calculus 4

2.2 The Laplace Transform 5

2.3 Deterministic Optimal Control 6

2.4 Stochastic Optimal Control 6

3 The Model 9

3.1 Definition of the Model 9

3.2 The Optimal Control Problem 10

3.3 The Switch Point 11

3.4 The Value Function 12

3.5 The Laplace Transform of the General Solution 12

4 Analysis of the Pure Diffusion Model 15

4.1 The Switch Point 15

4.2 The Value Function 16

4.3 Concavity of the Value Function 17

4.4 Numerical Study 18

4.4.1 The Value Function 19

4.4.2 The Switch Point 20

4.4.3 Sensitivity Against the Brownian Risk 23

5 Analysis of the Jump-Diffusion Model 25

5.1 A General Equation for the Switch Point 25

5.2 Numerical Study: The Price of Crude Oil 28

5.2.1 Estimation of the Parameters 29

5.2.2 The Switch Point 31

5.2.3 The Value Function 34

(7)

5.3 Conclusions 35

References 37

(8)

1 Introduction

1.1 The Problem

Imagine that we are fishermen; interested in determining how much salmon we can fish from a lake without threatening the survival of them. We can assume that the number of salmons in the lake evolves in time according to a diffusion process. But sometimes, rare events can occur that can kill many salmons at one point in time, e.g. natural disasters or wars. It is suitable to model these events by a Poisson process with a small intensity rate. This is important, as these events definitely have an impact on how many salmons we can fish without threatening their survival.

The problem of finding how many salmons that we can fish is an optimal control problem, in which we want to maximise the total number of salmons that we can fish, and in the same time we must make sure that they survive. This problem can be translated into many other examples, and they are all equivalent in a mathematical setting. We list some examples here, stating the key mathematical properties of each of them:

1. The number of salmons in a lake

Control function: How many we actually fish up.

Optimisation incentive: Maximise the total amount of salmons fished over time.

Conflict: If we fish too much, the survivals of salmons in the lake is threatened.

Constraint: Bound on maximum fishing capacity.

2. Cash reserve of a large company

Control function: Taking cash out for e.g. dividends and investments.

Optimisation incentive: Maximise the total amount of cash that we take out over time.

Conflict: Risk for liquidation if cash level becomes too small.

Constraint: Bound on maximum amount that we can take out at one point in time.

(9)

3. Prices of raw materials

Control function: How much to supply.

Optimisation incentive: Maximise the total supplied amount over time.

Conflict: If price becomes too low, it is not profitable to produce.

Constraint: Bound on suppliers' production capacity.

This Thesis will mainly be concerned with examples 2 and 3, but the problem can easily be translated into example 1 as well as other ones. Note that the examples are analysed under further assumptions, which we will present later.

By studying these examples, we see that the main problem is to find the specific control function that optimises the optimisation incentive and satisfies the constraint, and in the same time not takes the risk outlined in the conflict.

So what do we expect the solution to this problem to be? If we look at the second example, the optimisation incentive tells us to maximise the total amount of cash that we take out, so the answer should be to take out cash at the maximum possible speed. On the other hand, the conflict tells us to stop if the cash is below some level, so that there will not be risk for liquidation. The main difficulty is thus to find this "switch point" for which it is optimal to stop the payments. We are also interested in determining the value of all dividends paid out over time for a given cash level, which we optimised.

1.2 Objective

Our analysis is being based on the article by Jeanblanc and Shiryaev [2], in which this problem is analysed for a pure diffusion model. But this article is quite theoretic and not so accessible for non-mathematicians. Therefore, we will make parts of these results explicit and also do some numerical studies, which will serve as an important verification of the results and in the same time give us the possibility to visualise the results in various plots. This is possible as one gets an analytic solution that is relatively easy to deal with.

(10)

Further, we will look at the problem as described in the article by Belhaj [1], that presents the jump-diffusion model, the optimal control problem and solves it for some examples of the distribution of the jump's size. We will look at the case with an exponential distribution, as we will see that it is the easiest one to deal with. But in [1] no conclusions are drawn concerning qualitative properties of the results. Our objective is to analyse the qualitative properties by conducting some numerical investigations. The difficulty with this model is that it is too difficult to derive an analytic solution in this case, so we must rely on numerical examples.

1.3 Organisation of the Thesis

SECTION 2: In section 2 we will provide the prerequisites necessary to understand the mathematical formulation of the problem, i.e. basic definitions from stochastic calculus and some information on the Laplace transform, that we will use to solve the optimisation problem. We will also set up the general optimal control problem in both the deterministic and stochastic case.

SECTION 3: In Section 3 we will present the jump-diffusion model we will analyse.

We present methods to obtain the switch point and the value function. We also determine the Laplace transform for the general solution explicitly.

SECTION 4: Section 4 will be concerned with analysing the pure diffusion model. In this case it is quite easy to determine the switch point and the value function. We show that the value function is always concave in this case, which is not generally true when we work with the jump-diffusion model. We also study the nature of the solution by numerical studies.

SECTION 5: In Section 5 we will analyse the jump-diffusion model when the size of the jumps is exponentially distributed. We derive a general equation for the switch point. Then we look at the crude oil price and estimates parameters based on this data.

After that we do some numerical studies to analyse what happens when we allow one or more jumps to occur.

(11)

2 Preliminaries

2.1 Stochastic Calculus

2.1.1 DEFINITION: A σ-algebra F on Ω is a collection of subsets on Ω such that It is not empty; ∅∈F and Ω∈F;

If AF then AcF; and

If A1, A2, ... ∈F then A F and .

i i

U

=1

I

i=1AiF

2.1.2 DEFINITION: (Ω,F,P) is a probability space if Ω is the set of all possible outcomes, is a σ-algebra and

F P denotes the probability function.

2.1.3 DEFINITION: A collection {Ft}t>0 of σ-algebras on Ω is a filtration if t

s F

Fst ∀ 0≤ ≤ .

2.1.4 DEFINITION: A stochastic process x is a collection of random variables defined on a probability space

} ,

), ( { } ,

{xt tT = xt α tT α∈Ω (Ω,F,P).

2.1.5 DEFINITION: A stochastic process is a standard Wiener process (or a Brownian motion) if

} 0

{wt t>

;

0 =0 w

has stationary independent increments, i.e.

} 0

{wt t> wtws has the same distribution

as wt+hws+h ∀ ,t sT such that t+ ,h s+hT and ∀ tiT such that t1 < ...<tn and n≥1 we have that are independent random variables;

1 1

2 − , ... , −

n

n t

t t

t w w w

w

; and ) , 0 (

~ ,

0 w N t

t > t

has continuous sample paths.

} 0

{wt t>

(12)

2.1.6 REMARK: We have that dwt ~ N(0, dt) as dwtdt where ε is a random drawing from a standardised normal distribution.

2.1.7 DEFINITION: A stochastic process is a Poisson process if it satisfies the first and second properties of the standard Wiener process, and

} 0

{Nt t>

, where Poi denotes the Poisson distribution. For example, it has the following properties (called the Poisson Postulates):

) (

~ ,

0 N Poi t

t > t λ

The number of events occurring in nonoverlapping time intervals are independent;

The probability structure is time-invariant;

The probability of exactly one event in an infinitesimal interval is approximately proportional to its length; and

The probability of finding more than one event in an infinitesimal interval is smaller than the probability of finding one.

2.2 The Laplace Transform

2.2.1 DEFINITION: The function y = y(t) defined on t∈[0,∞) belongs to L2[0,∞) if

<

0

|2

) (

| y t dt

2.2.2 DEFINITION: The Laplace transform of a function y(t)∈ L2[0,∞) is a function Ly(ξ) defined as

Ly =

0

) ( )

e ξty t dt

The Laplace transform satisfies several nice properties. For example,

L(ξ)=ξ⋅Ly(ξ) −y(0), so one can use Laplace transforms to transform differential equations into algebraic equations.

(13)

2.3 Deterministic Optimal Control

2.3.1 DEFINITION: u(x) is called a utility function if u(0)=0 and if u is a strictly concave continuously differentiable function, such that the derivative decreases strictly from to 0.

)

´(x u xa

∞ +

2.3.2 EXAMPLE: A common example of a utility function is u(x)= x.

2.3.3 THE PROBLEM: The deterministic optimal control problem is set up as follows: Let be a utility function and

) (x

u ρ>0 a discount factor. The problem is to find the function that maximises

) (x u

0

)) ( (x t dt u

e ρt &

Therefore, we let

J( A)= Max

0

)) ( (x t dt u

e ρt &

where dt

x&= dx and we have the condition , which expresses the total disposal of

resources.

A dt t x ⋅ =

0

)

&(

2.3.4 THE SOLUTION: The solution to this problem is according to Euler given by the differential equation:

) 0

´(x C u

eρt ⋅ & = where C0 is a constant.

2.4 Stochastic Optimal Control

2.4.1 THE PROBLEM: The stochastic optimal control problem is set up as follows: We denote by the consumption and by the level of capital at time that is governed by the following process:

) (t

c {xt}t0 t

(14)

t t

t c t dt x dw

dx = ( )⋅ +σ ⋅ ⋅

where is a standard Wiener process and the in front of it means that we have a geometric process.

} 0

{wt t xt

>0

σ is the volatility constant of the Wiener process. The problem is to find the function tac(t) that maximises the expected value

0

)) (

(c t e dt u

E ρt

We also have the condition that the process stops if x(τ)=0 for some τ ≥0. We note that the solution to this problem is not given in advance. As a general reference we refer to the

account of stochastic optimisation as presented in chapter 20-21 in the book by Kamien- Schwartz.

2.4.2 THE SOLUTION: If the solution is not given in advance, how does one come about a solution to this problem? We start by defining

J(A;σ)= Max

0

)) (

(c t e dt u

E ρt

when the initial asset value is A, i.e. x(0)=A. To determine an expression of J(A;σ), we consider a small interval in time [0,δt] in which c(s)≡c for all 0≤s≤δt. The value at time

δ is approximately equal to t (1− )δt ⋅J(A;σ) if the value of the asset at time 0 is J(A;σ), since δ Jt⋅ (A;σ) is consumed in this time interval, given that the consumption is

maximised. This gives that the profit is equal to

t A

c

u( ) δ ρ J(A;σ)⋅δt

as we get what we consume in the time interval [0,δt] and we subtract the discounted value of this. This profit is approximately equal to

J(xδt;σ)=J(Ac⋅δtA⋅σ⋅dwδt;σ) where wδtis a random variable such that E(wδt)=0 and Var(wδt)=δt.

Using these properties and evaluating in a Taylor expansion yields the expected profit:

[

E J(xδt;σ)]= E[J(Ac⋅δt+A⋅σ ⋅dwδt;σ)]=

=J(A;σ)− c⋅J´ ⋅ ⋅ +

⋅ 2

)

; (

2

2 σ

δ σ t A

A J´´(A;σ)⋅ tδ + o( tδ )32 so we should choose the function so that we maximise c

− c c

u( ) J´(A;σ) ⇔ u´(c)= J´(A;σ)

(15)

where the fact that is strictly concave implies that the problem has a unique solution. u

(16)

3 The Model

In this section, we use the interpretation of the problem of optimising the flow of cash in a large company.

3.1 Definition of the Model

Let m be the cash held at time zero, µ ≥0 the constant growth rate, σ >0 the Brownian volatility rate,λ≥0 the intensity of the Poisson process and a random variable denoting the size of the Poisson jump. can be discrete or continuous.

} 0

{Nt t> s s

We make the following assumptions:

The liquidation value of the firm is zero, i.e. the firm goes into bankruptcy the first time its cash reserves becomes negative;

The firm has no access to external financing;

The firm has no possibility to invest its cash reserves in the stock market or in a risk- free asset.

Under the assumptions and definitions above, the firm’s cash reserves evolve according to the process:

t t t

t dt dw s dN dL

dm =µ⋅ +σ ⋅ − ⋅ −

where denotes the total amount of cash taken out up to time t. is assumed to be non-negative and right-continuous. In deciding the strategy at a time we only have access to the information given at that specific time, i.e. is adapted to a filtration .

is also assumed to be bounded by a so-called technological constraint, i.e. for some constant

} 0

{Lt t> Lt

Lt t

Lt {Ft}t>0

Lt Lt < K <∞

K . This is the bound on the maximum amount of cash that one can take out at one point in time.

(17)

3.1.1 REMARK: In reality, the constants µ, σ , λ and the distribution for in the model above should be estimated from empirical data using statistical estimation techniques. This means that when one inserts values of these parameters into the results derived in this Thesis one gets an inexact model that always involves some kind of error, which in turn can be estimated by observing the signal/noise ratio in the data and analysing the error of the estimation method one uses. This error should always be analysed before one starts using models that are inexact and the exactness of the results only depends on how good the

estimations of the parameters are. The truth lies in the empirical data, not in the mathematical models. These are just approximations of the data and should always be handled with care.

We should also say that Brownian motion in general is good for prediction, but bad with matching historical data – as it is a stochastic process.

s

3.2 The Optimal Control Problem

Recall from the introduction that we wanted to maximise the total amount of cash that we take out. The expected value of this is

= τ ρ

0

)

(m Em e tdLt V

where }τ =inf{t:m(t)≤0 is the moment of bankruptcy and ρ >0 is the discount factor. The expectation is taken conditioned on the initial reserve m. is called the value function or the optimal return function. By maximising the expected value like this, we expect the

optimal policy of taking out cash to be something like this: when the cash level is large enough, it is optimal to take out the amount

) (m V

K . And if the cash level is small, it is optimal to take out nothing. So the strategy itself is not so exciting. The main problem is to find what we call the switch point, below which we shall take out nothing. The existence of such a switch point and the solution to this optimal control problem is given by the following proposition:

3.2.1 PROPOSITION: There is a switch point m* such that

When mm*, we have that L(m)=0 and V and are given by the following equations:

* m

(18)

⎪⎩

⎪⎨

=

=

=

⋅ +

⋅ +

=

0 0

)

´(

0

*)

´´(

, 1

*)

´(

, 0 0

) (

)]

( ) ( [ )

´´(

)

´(

)

( 21 2

m m

V

m V m

V m

m V

m V s m V E m

V m

V m

V µ σ λ s

ρ

When m>m*, we have that L(m)=K and V(m)=mm*+V(m*).

We see that when , the marginal value of taking out cash equal the marginal value of retaining cash. The value function is reflected at this point; the solution is of "bang-bang"

type.

* m m=

3.3 The Switch Point

How does one find the switch point ? According to the above, we should proceed as follows:

* m

First, we find the function that solves f

⎪⎩

⎪⎨

=

=

⋅ +

⋅ +

0 0

) (

0 )]

( ) ( [ )

( )

´(

)

2 ´´(

2 1

m m

f

m f s m f E m

f m

f m

f µ ρ λ s

σ

Then the switch point is the unique point in the set that minimises .

*

m {m: f´´(m)=0, f´´´(m)>0} )

´(m f

3.3.1 REMARK: The equation that we have to solve is a partial integro-differential equation for non-zero λ, involving the two unknown functions and the frequency function for the jump size. The equation is only possible to solve analytically in a few cases, as we will see later. An interesting observation is to compare this equation with ones obtained when pricing options when the underlying stock follows a jump-diffusion process. If the option can be realised anytime of the holders choice, and if the holder also can choose how much of the invested value that he/she prefer to realise, we see that one is interested in finding the point in time when it is optimal to realise the option and how much it is optimal to realise at that time.

The solution will also in this case be of "bang-bang" type, i.e. at a given point in time it is optimal to either realise as much as you can or to realise nothing – depending on the current value of the underlying stock.

f

(19)

3.4 The Value Function

The value function as a function of the initial cash level m is:

⎪⎩

⎪⎨

<

+

= ≤

m m m V m m

m m m

f m f m

V

*

*), (

*

*

*),

´(

) ( )

(

3.4.1 REMARK: One observation we can make immediately is that for all , i.e. V is linear in this region. So when analysing concavity/convexity one only needs to consider the case when . We also see that the slope of the value function is always one after the switch point, independent of any of the parameters.

0 )

´´(m = V

* m m

* m m<

3.5 The Laplace Transform of the General Solution

To solve the problem, we will determine the Laplace transform of the general solution. This is as far as one can say things about the general solution without making any further

assumptions on the frequency function for the jump size.

3.5.1 PROPOSITION: If the function f is in L2[0,∞) and if f satisfies the equation

⎪⎩

⎪⎨

=

=

⋅ +

⋅ +

0 0

) (

0 )]

( ) ( [ )

( )

´(

)

2 ´´(

2 1

m m

f

m f s m f E m

f m

f m

f µ ρ λ s

σ

then f has the Laplace transform Lf (ξ)

] [ )

( ) 0

´(

2 2 2 1

2 2 1

s s e E f

+ +

⋅ +

= ⋅ ξ

λ λ ρ ξ µ ξ σ

σ

where s is a random variable.

PROOF: As f(0)=0, we have that Lf ´(ξ) =ξ⋅Lf (ξ) and Lf ´´(ξ) =ξ2⋅Lf (ξ) − f´(0). If we by saψ(s) denote the frequency function for s, the equation to solve becomes

(20)

⎪⎩

⎪⎨

=

=

⋅ +

⋅ +

⋅ +

0 0

) (

0 ) ( ) ( )

( ) ( )

´(

)

´´(

0 2

2 1

m m

f

ds s s m f m

f m

f m

f µ ρ λ λ ψ

σ

where the Laplace transform of the integral is

=

=

∫ ∫

∫ ∫

f t s s dsdt s e f t s dtds

e t t

0 0

0 0

) ( )

( )

( )

( ξ

ξ ψ ψ

⎥ =

⎢ ⎤

⎡ − + −

=

0 0

) ( )

( )

(s e f t s dt e f t s dt ds

s t s

t ξ

ψ ξ

=

=

=

∫ ∫

+

0 0

0 0

)

( ( ) ( )

) ( )

(t s dtds s e f t dtds e s

f ψ ξ t s ξsψ

=

∫ ∫

0

) ( )

(s e e tf t dtds

s

t ξ

ψ ξ

= Lf (ξ)

=

0

) ( dss

e ξ sψ Lf (ξ)⋅Es[eξs] We now take the Laplace transform of the whole equation, and obtain:

2

2 2

1σ [ξ Lf (ξ) − f´(0)]+µ⋅ξ⋅Lf (ξ) −(ρ+λ)⋅Lf (ξ) +λ⋅Lf (ξ)⋅Es

[ ]

eξs = 0 ⇒ Lf (ξ)⋅

[

+ ( + )+ [ ]

]

2 2 ´(0)=0

2 1 2 2

1σ ξ µ ξ ρ λ λ Es e ξs σ f

Lf (ξ)

] [ )

( ) 0

´(

2 2 2 1

2 2 1

s s e E f

+ +

⋅ +

= ⋅ ξ

λ λ ρ ξ µ ξ σ

σ

3.5.2 REMARK: We see that in general it will be very difficult to find the inverse Laplace transform and thereby an analytical expression for the function . In fact, the only cases we can analyse analytically are the ones when either

f

=0

λ (when we have a pure diffusion model) or when has an exponential distribution, as these are the only cases that makes both the nominator and the denominator of the Laplace transform algebraic.

s

3.5.3 REMARK: The function appears as a familiar and very useful tool in mathematical statistics.

] [ s

s e E ξ

3.5.4 EXAMPLE: Consider the case when is a discrete stochastic variable, denoting jumps that occur due to interest rate decisions. To be precise, we let

s

=1

s with probability ½ and with probability ½. Then we have that

=2

s Es[eξs]= 21(eξ +e2ξ) and the Laplace transform for the function f becomes

(21)

Lf (ξ)

) (

) (

) 0

´(

2 2

2 1 2 2 1

2 2 1

ξ

λ ξ

λ ρ ξ µ ξ σ

σ

+

⋅ + +

⋅ +

= ⋅

e e f

We see that in this case, the inverse Laplace transform is impossible to find without the use of advanced residue techniques.

(22)

4 Analysis of the Pure Diffusion Model

Throughout this section, we assume that there are no Poisson jump present in the model, i.e.

=0

λ . This case was studied by Jeanblanc and Shiryaev in 1995 [2]. Below, we shall make some of their results explicit and do some numerical investigations.

4.1 The Switch Point

4.1.1 PROPOSITION: The function f is

m b b e

m f

f = ´(0)⋅ am⋅sinh ⋅ )

(

where 2

σ

= µ

a and 2

2

2 2

σ σ ρ µ + ⋅

= b

PROOF: The Laplace transform of the function f becomes

Lf (ξ) ⎟⎟

⎜⎜ ⎞

+

− +

⋅ +

− =

⋅ +

= ⋅

b a b

a b

f f

ξ ρ ξ

ξ µ ξ σ

σ 1 1

2 ) 0 ) ´(

0

´(

2 2 2 1

2 2 1

so we have that

m b b e

e f b e

m f

f = ⋅ am+bmambm = ´(0)⋅ am⋅sinh ⋅ )

2 ( ) 0 ) ´(

(

if we let 2 σ

= µ

a and 2

2

2 2

σ σ ρ µ + ⋅

=

b .

4.1.2 PROPOSITION:Assuming that f´(0)>0, we have that the switch point is

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

= b a

a b m b1 ln

*

where 2

σ

= µ

a and 2

2

2 2

σ σ ρ µ + ⋅

=

b

PROOF: By taking derivatives we obtain:

(23)

] cosh sinh

) [ 0 ) ´(

´( e a b m b b m

b m f

f = ⋅ am⋅ − ⋅ ⋅ + ⋅ ⋅

] cosh 2

sinh ) ) [(

0 ) ´(

´´( e a2 b2 b m a b b m

b m f

f = ⋅ am⋅ + ⋅ ⋅ − ⋅ ⋅ ⋅

] cosh ) 3

( sinh

) 3 ( ) [

0 ) ´(

´´´( e a a2 b2 b m b a2 b2 b m

b m f

f = ⋅ am⋅ − ⋅ + ⋅ ⋅ + ⋅ + ⋅ ⋅

Letting gives that f´´(m*)=0

=

+ ) sinh * 2 cosh * 0

(a2 b2 b m a b b m

= +

+ ) [ ] 2 [ ] 0

(a2 b2 ebm* e bm* a b ebm* e bm*

0 ] 2 [

] 2 [

0 ] 1 [

2 ] 1 [

)

(a2 +b2e2bm*− − abe2bm* + = ⇔ e2bm*a2 +b2aba2 +b2 + ab =

⎟ ⇔

⎜ ⎞

= +

⎟ ⇔

⎜ ⎞

= +

⇔ +

=

2 2

* 2 2

2

*

2 ( ) ( ) 2 * ln

b a

b m a

b b a

b e a

b a b a

e bm bm

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

= b a

a b m b1 ln

* as we have that a<b.

We have to analyse when f´´´(m*)>0, which is when f´(0)>0 as seen by rewriting f´´´ as

= +

⋅ +

⋅ + + +

⋅ +

= + [ ( 3 3 ) 3 3 ]

2 ) 0 ) ´(

´´´( e ( ) e2 a3 a b2 a2 b b3 a3 a b2 a2 b b3

b m f

f m a b bm

] ) ( ) ( 2 [

) 0

´( ( ) 2 3 3

a b a b e

b e

fm a bbm⋅ − + +

= +

4.2 The Value Function

4.2.1 PROPOSITION: The value function is given by

⎪⎪

⎪⎪

⎟<

⎜ ⎞

⋅ + + −

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

⎟ ⋅

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

=

a m b

a b b a b

a a

b a b m b

a b

a b m b

m b a e

b a b m b

V

m b a a

1 ln 2 ,

1 ln

1 ln ,

1 sinh )

(

2 2

where 2

σ

= µ

a and 2

2

2 2

σ σ ρ µ + ⋅

= b

PROOF: Inserting the switch point m* into f´ we obtain

(24)

=

⋅ +

= ´(0) [ sinh * cosh *]

*)

´( e * a b m b b m

b m f

f am

= +

⋅ +

= [ ( ) ( )]

2 ) 0

´( am* bm* bm* bm* bm*

e e b e

e a b e

f

= + +

= +

⋅ +

= + + [ ( ) ]

2 ) 0 )] ´(

1 (

) 1 (

2 [ ) 0

´( *( ) 2 * 2 * *( ) 2 *

a b a b e

b e e f

b e

a b e

f m a b bm bm m a b bm

⎥⎦

⎢ ⎤

⎡ + +

− +

⋅ +

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

⎥=

⎥⎦

⎢⎢

⎡ ⎟ ⋅ − + +

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

a a b

b

a b a b a

b a b b a f

b a a b

b a b a

b a b b

f b

a b

a

2 1 2

2

1 2

2 ) 0 ) ´(

2 ( ) 0

´(

b a b

a b

a

a b

a f b

a b

a f b

a b

b a b a

b a b b

f

⎜ ⎞

⎛ +

⋅ −

⎟ =

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

⎥=

⎢ ⎤

⋅ +

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

=

) 0

´(

) 0 2 ´(

2 2

) 0

´( 1 2

so we have that

m b a e

b a b b m f

m

f b am

a

⎟ ⋅

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

= 1 sinh

*)

´(

) (

and

=

⎟ ⋅

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

=1 sinh *

*)

´(

*)

( *

m b a e

b a b b m f

m

f b am

a

=

⎟ ⋅

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

=

⎟ ⋅

⎜ ⎞

⋅ + [ + ]

2 ] 1 2 [

1 * * * b m*(a b) m*(a b)

a m

b m b m b a a

e a e

b a b e b

e a e

b a b b

⎥⎦=

⎢⎣ ⎤

+

− −

⋅ +

⎥=

⎢⎢

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

− +

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

⎟⎠

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

+

a b

a b a b

a b b a

b a b a

b a b a

b a b b

b a b

a b

a

2 1 2

1 1 1

2 2 2 2 2

2

2

2 4 2

2 1 )

( ) ( 2

1

a b

a a

b b a b a

b

a b a b

b ⎥⎦⎤= −

⎢⎣⎡

⋅ ⋅

⎥=

⎢ ⎤

⋅ +

4.3 Concavity of the Value Function

We recall from earlier observations that V´´(m)=0 for all . The following proposition provides a robust result that not holds in the case with a non-zero

* m m

λ, as we will see in the next section.

(25)

4.3.1 PROPOSITION: V´´(m)<0 for all m<m*, i.e. the function V is strictly concave in this interval.

PROOF: = = ⋅ ⋅ ⋅[( + )⋅sinh ⋅ −2 ⋅ ⋅cosh ⋅ ]=

*)

´(

) 0

´(

1

*)

´(

) ) ´´(

´´( e a2 b2 b m a b b m

m f

f b m f

m m f

V am

= +

⋅ +

⎟ ⋅

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

= [( ) ( ) 2 ( )]

2

1 b am 2 2 bm bm bm bm

a

e e b a e

e b a a e

b a b b

0 )]

1 (

2 ) 1 (

) 2 [(

1 ⎟ ⋅ ( )2 + 22 − − ⋅ ⋅ 2 + <

⎜ ⎞

⋅ +

= b a+bm bm bm

a

e b a e

b a a e

b a b b if

* 0

) ( ) (

2 2

2 2

2 m m

b a

b e a

b a b a

e bm bm ⎟ ⇔ <

⎜ ⎞

< +

<

+

which was assumed.

4.4 Numerical Study

The objective with this section is to analyse the results obtained in the pure diffusion model for various values of the parameters. We start by observing the components of the value function and we expect it to be concave up to the switch point and linear after that. Then we will study the switch point and how it depends on the parameters. We expect it to be

increasing with σ and decreasing with ρ. But how does it depend on µ? Our calculations will show that this dependence looks like the beta distribution, an interesting fact that may have economic implications. Finally we will study when the firm is sensitive towards the Brownian risk induced by a non-zero σ . We will show that when σ is small the firm is sensitive up to the switch point, and when σ increases above some switch point, the firm is sensitive up to a point below the switch point that will converge quite fast to zero.

(26)

4.4.1 The Value Function

II

9 I 9

V V

0 0

0 4m 0 m 4

III IV

9 9

V V

0 0

0 4m 0 m 4

4.4.1.1 FIGURE:In this figure, the two components of the value function are plotted. The value function follows the function that starts at zero, and when it reaches the switch point it switches to follow the linear line. We see that the value function is indeed concave up to the switch point, and after that it becomes linear (i.e. either concave or convex).

The parameter values are as follows:

) (m V ma

I: 2µ =1/ , σ =1/3, 10ρ =1/ II: 2µ =1/ , σ =1/3, 5ρ =1/ III: 2µ =1/ , σ =1/5, 10ρ =1/ IV: 3µ =1/ , σ =1/3, 10ρ =1/

(27)

4.4.2 The Switch Point

We will next study what happens when we let one of the parameters be free, and we fix the rest of them at the same values as above.

II

* m

7

0 7 I

* m

0

σ 0 σ 10

0 10

III

* m

7

0

σ

0 10

4.4.2.1 FIGURE: The function σ am*(σ). Of course we were expecting the switch point to be an increasing function of σ , as a larger σ means a greater risk and therefore the firm needs to retain more cash against possible liquidation. On the other hand, if σ converges towards zero, there is no need to retain any cash as the model gets deterministic, i.e. the σ - risk is eliminated. This is kind of a strange solution, as it is optimal to take out everything, wait until the cash grows with µ and then take everything out once again. The parameter values are as follows:

I: 2µ =1/ , 10ρ =1/

(28)

II: 2µ =1/ , 5ρ =1/ III: 3µ =1/ , 10ρ =1/

I

* m

1.5

0

II

* m

1.5

0

ρ

0 5 0 ρ 5

III

* m

1.5

0

ρ

0 5

4.4.2.2 FIGURE: The function ρ am*(ρ). We see that the switch point starts declining rapidly when ρ increases if we start at zero, and we see that ρ must be held sufficiently small for the switch point to not converge to zero. So the switch point is very sensitive to changes in the discount factor! The special thing with the discount factor is that it is an external parameter compared to the other ones that are given from data generated internally within the firm. The discount factor “decides” how profitable it is to retain cash compared to consuming and this figure illustrates how the relationship with discount factor looks like. The parameter values are as follows:

I: 2µ =1/ , σ =1/3

(29)

II: 2µ =1/ , σ =1/5 III: 3µ =1/ , σ =1/3

1.5 1.5

I II

*

m m*

0 0

µ µ

0 5 0 5

1.5 III

* m

0

µ

0 5

4.4.2.3 FIGURE:The function µ am*(µ). We see that this function has a shape similar to a beta distribution; it starts at zero, it is concave up to a maximum point and then convex after that. This is less intuitive than the other plots. The existence of a maximum point can be explained by the following conflict: The fact that the firm goes into ruin quite fast because of the σ >0 gives that a larger value of µ is desirable. On the other hand, if µ is too large then the firm does not need to retain any cash as the large µ provides a guarantee that cash will flow in fast. We see that when µ converges towards zero; the switch point converges towards zero. It is thus optimal to not retain any cash when µ is zero as the σ -risk can bring it down.

The parameter values are as follows:

I: σ =1/3, 10ρ =1/

(30)

II: σ =1/3, 5ρ =1/ III: σ =1/5, 10ρ =1/

4.4.3 Sensitivity Against the Brownian Risk

Finally, we discuss a variation, which perhaps is a bit tentative. The sensitivity is studied by observing the sign of the derivative of the value function with respect to σ . When , this derivative is independent of and thus it has the same sign for all (it is positive).

Then the firm is not sensitive to the Brownian risk. When

* m m>

m m

* m

m≤ , the derivative of the value function with respect to σ is a function of , so for a fixed value of m σ there is in the pure diffusion model one point for which the sign of the derivative changes. This means that for smaller than this point the derivative is negative and the firm is sensitive to the Brownian risk – and for larger than this point the firm is not sensitive. We note that there is just one such point, as indicated by the following figure:

m

m

=0

∂ σ V ) (

* σ m

5

m

0

σ

0 3

4.4.3.1 FIGURE: The function that starts in 0 is the switch point as function of σ . This is plotted as this is the upper bound on for which the plot is valid. The other function is obtained by letting the derivative of the value function with respect to

m

σ be equal to zero and taking out m as a function of σ , to see at which values of that the sign of this derivative changes. We see that for

m

σ smaller than the intersection between these two functions, we

(31)

have that the sign changes at the switch point ; the firm is thus sensitive up to the switch point. In this figure the intersection point between the two functions is approx. and

* m

35 .

=1 m 8

.

=0

σ . For σ larger than that, the figure indicates that there is a point less than for which the sign changes. This means that even if the cash goes below the switch point the firm does not need to be sensitive for the Browninan risk. The parameter values are:

* m

2 /

=1 µ , 10

/

=1

ρ .

References

Related documents

In applications wavelets are often used together with a multiresolution analysis (MRA) and towards the end it will be shown how a wavelet basis is constructed from a

With other restrictions Helly’s theorem can also be expanded to an infinite collections of convex sets, while without any additional conditions the original Helly’s theorem is

Här visas också att förlorade sampelvärden för en översamplad funktion kan återskapas upp till ett godtyckligt ändligt antal.. Konvergenshastigheten för sampling

In this paper we will present formalizations of two paradoxes that can be seen as versions of Russell’s paradox in the inconsistent version of Martin-L¨ of’s type theory:

hα, βi där integralen konvergerar kallas för den fundamentala remsan.. I den fundamentala remsan är

3.2.2.10 A stricter definition of the integral and the fundamental theorem of calculus Armed with a better understanding of limits and continuity, as well as perhaps a firmer

Let us say we want to lift this system to the base period h.. Discrete lifting to enable state realization. As suggested by the dierent linings for the signals in the gure,

Aczel showed that CZF can be interpreted in Martin Löf’s type theory by considering a type of sets, hence giving CZF a constructive meaning.. In this master’s thesis we review