• No results found

Terrorism Financing, Recruitment and Attacks: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Pakistan∗

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Terrorism Financing, Recruitment and Attacks: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Pakistan∗"

Copied!
56
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Terrorism Financing, Recruitment and Attacks: Evidence from a Natural Experiment in Pakistan

Nicola Limodio

August 2018

Abstract

I investigate the relation between terrorism financing and attacks through a panel of 1,545 Pakistani cities and exogenous variation in a Sharia-compliant funding source. Cities exposed to higher terrorism financing experience more attacks, with organizations reacting to temporary financial inflows. Two methodological innovations further refine this finding.

First, the effect of financing on attacks increases in terrorist recruitment, measured using dark-web data on Jihadist fora and machine-learning. Second, a novel city-organization variation allows: a) dissecting the demand and supply of terrorist attacks, with supply exclusively explaining these results; b) estimating the elasticity of terrorist attacks to financing (0.08).

JEL: H56, G30, D64

Keywords: Terrorism, Finance, Charitable Donations

I would like to express my gratitude for their useful suggestions to Charles Angelucci, Giorgia Barboni, Eli Berman, Tim Besley, Barbara Biasi, Christopher Blattman, Leah Platt Boustan, Sandro Brusco, Ethan Bueno de Mosquita, Elena Carletti, James Choi, Decio Coviello, Paolo Colla, Ben Crost, Filippo De Marco, Erika Deserranno, Livio Di Lonardo, Will Dobbie, Tiberiu Dragu, Oeindrila Dube, Carlo Ambrogio Favero, Martin Feldstein, Dana Foarta, Thomas Fujiwara, Rohan Ravindra Gudibande, Selim Gulesci, Nicola Gennaioli, Elisa Giannone, Massimo Guidolin, Dejan Kovac, Alan Krueger, Eliana La Ferrara, Simone Lenzu, Alessandro Lizzeri, Rocco Macchiavello, Alberto Manconi, Hani Mansour, Luis Martinez, Rachel Meager, Massimo Morelli, Gerard Padr´o i Miquel, Jacopo Perego, Jos´e-Luis Peydr´o, Nicola Persico, Paolo Pinotti, Pablo Querub´ın, Julien Sauvagnat, Shanker Satyanath, David Schoenherr, Jacob N. Shapiro, David Silver, Meredith Startz, Maria Micaela Sviatschi, Guido Tabellini, Gianluca Violante, Austin Wright, Luigi Zingales and seminar participants at Bocconi, the 14th CSEF-IGIER Symposium on Economics and Institutions, Harris School of Public Policy, LSE Finance and Development Workshop, NBER SI Economics of National Security, New York University, Princeton University and the 2018 Qu´ebec Political Economy Conference. I thank Matthew S. Gerber for his initial data, the Artificial Intelligence Lab at the University of Arizona for providing useful material on dark web data and Nick Koutroumpinis for outstanding technical support. Edoardo Marchesi provided phenomenal research assistance. I am grateful for the financial support of the Junior Researcher’s Grants at Bocconi University, the Einaudi Institute for Economics and Finance and the Private Enterprise Development in Low- Income Countries. I am responsible for all errors.

nicola.limodio@unibocconi.it,www.nicolalimodio.com, Bocconi University, BAFFI CAREFIN, IGIER and LEAP, Via Roentgen 1, 20136 Milan, Italy.

(2)

1 Introduction

Guaranteeing a safe economic environment and protecting property rights is acknowledged as central in promoting growth and development. Introducing suitable policies to counter criminal and illegal activities necessitates a thorough understanding of their underlying functioning.

Among the various threats, terrorism has been particularly severe over the past decade because of its capacity to combine violence against civilians with media presence, global recruitment and para-military training. Such initiatives are able to instil a culture of fear and increased risk, which can result in large human and emotional costs, beyond severely adverse economic and financial outcomes. As the left panel of Figure 1 shows, the past decade has seen an unprecedented rise in the number of terrorist attacks all over the world.

Among the various causes behind this surge, the financing of terrorist organizations is con- sidered key (Feldstein(2008)) and policy makers have been trying to curb this link for decades.

For example, the General Assembly of the United Nations adopted the “International Conven- tion for the Suppression of the Financing of Terrorism” on December 9th, 1999.1 Such initiatives considerably expanded in the aftermath of 9/11 and various funding sources have been progres- sively placed under stricter scrutiny for terrorism financing (e.g. banks, charities, payment platforms, et cetera).2 Since then, nearly all countries introduced regulatory frameworks and agencies to toughen their control over terrorism financing and prevent illicit behaviour.3 How- ever, despite such initiatives, there is a lack of studies exploring the relation between terrorism and finance. This is problematic and expensive for two key reasons. First, it has contributed to tense judicial trials over whether governments have the right to block such funds, with cases of deadlock juries and out-of-court settlements motivated by poor evidence.4 Second, it limits the work of counter-terrorism in identifying dangerous financial transactions and understanding which sources of finance can affect attacks, how and over which horizon.

This research investigates the relation between terrorism financing and terrorist attacks in a middle-income country, Pakistan, that exhibits an evolution of terror attacks in line with the rest of the world (Figure 1, right panel). My findings highlight that: 1) the timing of finance affects the timing of attacks; 2) there exists a complementarity between finance and labour in producing attacks; 3) the increase in attacks is entirely explained by more active terrorist organizations. These results uncover novel insights into the functioning of terrorist groups for two reasons. First, the presence of a close relation between attacks and financing points

1Refer to the UN websitehttps://www.un.org/law/cod/finterr.htm

2For example, on September 24th, 2001, President George W. Bush signed an executive order to block the funds of organizations suspected of being involved with terrorism. Refer to the State Department archive from September 24, 2001,https://2001-2009.state.gov/s/ct/rls/rm/2001/5041.htm

3For example, the Treasury Department of the United States took the lead in this direction by empowering the OFAC (Office of Foreign Assets Control) and the TFI (Office of Terrorism and Financial Intelligence).

4Refer to New York Times, October 22nd, 2007, http://www.nytimes.com/2007/10/22/us/

22cnd-holyland.html, and to the American Bar Association Journal, June 4th, 2008, http:

//www.abajournal.com/news/article/fedl_judge_voids_jury_convictions_in_islamic_charity_

jihad_case/, for the case of the “Holy Land Foundation for Relief and Development” accused of funnelling charity funds to terrorists. Refer to the New York Times, August 14th 2015, for the case of “Arab Bank” accused of terrorism-financing https://www.nytimes.com/2015/08/15/nyregion/

arab-bank-reaches-settlement-in-suit-accusing-it-of-financing-terrorism.html

(3)

toward organizations being subject to a series of financial frictions (e.g. credit constraints, poor storage technology, et cetera). In fact, in the opposite scenario, a temporary shock to the funding of an extremist organization may be smoothed, across time and locations and hence, not necessarily generate an immediate and local attack. Second, this finding highlights that credit constraints may be the single most important constraint for terrorist groups in this setting and that alternative constraints (e.g. labour market frictions, political connections et cetera) may be less binding than finance.

Pakistan is the ideal country to conduct this study, because it presents a unique natural experiment that induces exogenous variation in a particular source of terrorism financing over time and across cities: charitable donations. The key source of variation is offered by the Zakat levy in Pakistan. When Ramadan arrives, Muslims are expected to give a charitable donation to the poor, the Zakat. While this contribution is left as an individual choice in most countries, since 1981 the Pakistani government has been imposing a mandatory contribution on its citizens, whose proceedings are collected by the government in the form of a 2.5% levy on bank deposits. Such funds are then directly spent by the government all over the country through local centres that provide food, shelter, medicines and cash to vulnerable groups (e.g.

chronic poor, blind and disabled people, widows, et cetera).5 However, individuals typically donate above the mandatory contribution either directly to another individual or by transferring funds through the multiple charities operating in Pakistan, which specialize in collecting Zakat donations.6

In this project, I exploit three features of the Zakat levy that create exogenous variation in city-level charitable donations. First, the timing of the donation. Because both the charity payments and the levy take place on the first day of Ramadan, I benefit from the lunar calendar and the fact that Ramadan dates move over time (from April 4th in 1992 to November 16th in 2001, to June 17th in 2015). This permits the netting out of seasonality and agricultural cycles that may independently affect terrorism via income shocks. Second, there exists an eligibility threshold on taxable deposits: individuals below the threshold are not taxed and give their contribution through charities or personally, while those above the threshold face this tax, which lowers their disposable income and, hence, donations. A special feature of the threshold is given by its relation to the international price of silver. The legal definition of threshold stems from a local interpretation of Sharia law and is given by the monetary value of 600 grams of silver. This is central, as local authorities announce the value of threshold only two days before Ramadan and compute it using the international price of silver on the specific day. This particular feature makes the revenue collection move inversely to silver prices, while charitable donations react with a positive sign. In fact, when silver prices are low, the threshold declines, more deposits are taxable, more donations transit through the government and fewer through private charities. On the contrary, high silver prices imply lower tax revenue

5Refer to the government website on Zakat for an overview of the programs http://www.zakat.gop.pk/

Programs

6Pakistan is one of the countries with the highest share of philanthropic donations in South Asia.

Refer to the report by Charities Aid Foundation, https://www.cafonline.org/about-us/publications/

2015-publications/caf-world-giving-index-2015

(4)

and higher charitable donations. Therefore, this element creates time-series fluctuations in the amounts that the government collects and, consequently, charities receive over time. Given that Pakistan is neither a top 20 producer nor consumer of such commodity,7I take the price of silver as being exogenously determined to the Pakistani economy. The third aspect induces cross- sectional variation. As Pakistan is a Sunni Islamic Republic, this levy only applies to Sunni Muslim and neither Shia Muslim, nor other religious groups pay this levy. This is fundamental for my analysis, because by digitizing a religious map of the country, I characterize each city as being Sunni-majority (treated) or not Sunni-majority (control).

In the first part of my empirical analysis, I illustrate three stylized facts in line with my first-stage: 1) the Zakat collection by the central government declines with silver prices; 2) indi- vidual Zakat donations increase when silver prices are high in Sunni locations, while individual receptions decline; 3) the total donations received by charities, expressed through their balance sheets, are highly correlated with silver prices. These facts show that, as silver prices increase, donations grow in Sunni-majority areas (as fewer individuals are taxed) while individual recep- tions of charity decline. Such reduction in receptions is not trivial, given that other possible economic effects of silver are controlled by the difference-in-difference specification (combining both non-Sunni areas as a control and time fixed effects). Hence, these results are consistent with charities receiving more funds when silver prices are high and, in these cases, funneling a larger share toward illicit groups. While individuals may not choose to donate to extremist groups directly, some charities may be associated with extremist groups more or less directly, as I document in Section 2.

In the second part, I offer reduced-form evidence at city-level on the relation between the price of silver before Ramadan and attacks. My results show that the probability of an attack, or their number, is not statistically different between Sunni and non-Sunni cities prior to Ramadan.

However, this difference becomes large and statistically different from zero only during the Ramadan and following quarter (when donations are made) and only when silver prices are high (more Sunni donations). Beyond the probability and number of terrorist attacks, also the attack-related killed and wounded individuals increase. In particular, there is an escalation in bombings, assassinations and unarmed attacks, while other types of events (e.g. Hijacking, Kidnapping, Infrastructure attacks et cetera) do not change.

In order to explore further the effects of terrorism financing on attacks, I offer two novel methodologies that go beyond the current research and could be extended to studying the role of organizations in conflict and crime. First, I construct a time-varying measure of terrorist recruitment through a machine-learning approach, as pioneered by Scanlon and Gerber(2014).

For this reason, I downloaded more than 17 million messages from 28 Jihadist fora operat- ing in the dark web in five languages between 2000 and 2012. An initial sample of random messages were offered to two judges, who manually and independently “graded” each message

7Refer to the statistics on silver for 2012 to 2014 provided by the United States Geological Survey, published by the United States Department of the Interior, available at http://minerals.usgs.gov/minerals/pubs/

commodity/silver/mcs-2014-silve.pdf, and the World Silver Survey 2015, issued by the Silver Institute, available athttps://www.silverinstitute.org/site/publications/.

(5)

with a dummy whenever it contained an intent to recruit violent extremists to some group or movement. This information was then used to design an algorithm that, exploiting supervised learning and natural language processing, assigned a dummy to all messages presenting recruit- ment material. This is conceptually in line with the work ofMueller and Rauh(2018), who use machine learning to extract topics from newspaper analysis, which are then used to predict the onset of a conflict. I use this measure to verify that the effect of terrorism financing on attacks is significantly stronger in period of intense terrorist recruitment in Pakistan. Such hetero- geneity is consistent with a complementarity between capital (finance, charity donations) and labour (new recruits) in producing terrorist events. The second methodological contribution of the paper focuses on dissecting the effect that this natural experiment may induce on the supply of terrorist attacks by extremist organizations (because of increased funding) and on the demand by city-level conditions (because of concurrent effects on the local labour market, local religiosity, military and/or policing et cetera). In order to implement this method, I build an additional panel that follows a set of terrorist organizations in every city and over time and code each terrorist organization as being Sunni (treatment) or non-Sunni (control). As a result, I can study the within-city within-organization variation by focusing on terrorist attacks due to the supply of events by terrorist organizations (controlling for organization fixed effects and city- time fixed effects) or the demand at city-level (through city and organization-time fixed effects).

This is in line with the methodology used in finance to dissect credit supply from demand, as introduced by Khwaja and Mian (2005) and Khwaja and Mian (2008). This methodological device contributes to a literature in conflict, and in particular the work of Dube and Vargas (2013), who pioneered the dissection of demand and supply of conflict by identifying shocks to labour intensive versus non-intensive commodities in Colombia. My results show that the supply of terrorist attacks by organizations is the only significant determinant of the increase in terrorism and quantitatively accounts for all the increase in attacks generated by the Zakat experiment. This result is in line with the work of Benmelech et al.(2012) and Krueger(2017), showing that labour market shocks do not have a direct effect on terrorist attacks and, hence, a limited role of terrorism demand. I cross-validate this finding by studying the city-level wages for the 40 largest cities in Pakistan and verifying the lack of a response to the Zakat natural experiment.

In addition to this, I join the city-organization dataset with the individual data on charity donations. In so doing, I can measure the financing that each organization receives in a year and in a certain geographic area (division), by combining information on the overall donations with data on the presence of each organization in each area through a Bartik instrument. As a result, I can offer an OLS estimate of the elasticity of terrorist attacks to financing (0.02) and, then, instrument the financing through the Zakat experiment. The IV estimate indicates a much larger elasticity, 0.08, which provides a useful element for further research on quantifying the benefits and costs of counter-terrorism operations. The final element of my analysis exploits an alternative Islamic celebration that offers the ideal placebo: Eid Adha. This takes place two quarters after Ramadan and is also an important period of festivals and family gatherings; in

(6)

particular, donations and gifts are given to family and the poor. Because there is no explicit connection to silver prices (no levies, no silver-related behaviour), I replicate my empirical strategy and cannot reject a zero effect of silver in Sunni-majority areas on terrorism in this celebration.

This work contributes to a literature on the organizational economics of terrorist and violent groups. The contributions of Berman (2011) andShapiro(2013) are pioneering in this respect, because they show how terrorist organizations are sophisticated in their reward structure, re- spond to traditional incentives (e.g. risk-sharing, career-concerns, et cetera) and mix economics and political motives, that go beyond religion and afterlife. Shapiro and Siegel (2007) intro- duces in this literature the role of finance and the fact that, while some large scale organizations may enjoy significant funding, their local level operatives may be cash constrained because of agency problems (e.g. monitoring the funds, misalignment of objectives). This argument is consistent with my results: as local level operatives receive a funding shock, this generates more attacks. Bueno de Mesquita (2005) shows that disrupting the financial network of ter- rorist organizations may be preferable to alternative crackdown strategies by the government (e.g. closing borders, abusive policing and interrogation, imposing curfews et cetera), because this may generate lower mobilization and ideological opposition. These results confirm that disrupting the financing of terrorist organizations can have significant and strong effects in reducing attacks, offering also an elasticity to benchmark such effects. My results are also in line with the work of Wright (2016), who shows how both the level of conflict and their tactics (terrorism versus conventional war) depend on their financing, identified by exploiting shocks to coca prices in Colombia. Crost et al.(2016) offers evidence compatible with an organization- financing channel in the Philippines, combining swings in global commodity prices with groups’

extortions of agricultural export firms. An alternative perspective on finance and terrorism is offered by Berman et al. (2011), who show that an increase in funding and strengthening of local public goods lowered terrorist attacks in Iraq, which would translate as a decline in the local demand for terrorist attacks. In terms of the type of attacks implemented by terrorists, Bueno de Mesquita(2013) shows that extremist groups rationally decide their tactic depending on its ex-post effects on mobilization and recruitment. In line with this, Reese et al. (2017) study the effect of the Islamic calendar on violence and do not find evidence of an increase in violent attacks at Ramadan in Iraq, Afghanistan, and Pakistan, because of an anticipated popular backlash. While this is true on average, this paper adds a key financial dimension that may have heterogeneous effects across periods and locations. In addition to this, the work of Dell and Querubin (2017) shows that the choice of certain attack strategies can directly affect the final outcome that an organization may achieve, by providing causal evidence on the military and political activities of insurgents in Vietnam. Through this framework, it may be possible to reinterpret the increase in bombings, assaults and unarmed attacks (e.g. chemical, biological or radiological attacks) but not in other attack types as dictated by the strategic motives of terrorist groups. The existence of a relation between the Zakat donations, terrorism financing and attacks has been highlighted since 9/11. For example, Basile (2004) notes the

(7)

link between Zakat donations, its misuse by charities and attacks, recommending a stronger oversight by governments. Levi(2010) discusses how such specific donations are hard to tackle given the current anti-money laundering initiatives and that they do not classify as proceeds from criminal activities. Milton-Edwards (2017) focuses on the Middle East and shows how a stricter oversight of the Palestinian Zakat committees by Israel and the Palestinian Authority became a powerful device of counter-terrorism, by limiting the activities of propaganda and vio- lence. From a quantitative perspective,Aman-Rana(2014) andAman-Rana (2017) explore the economic causes of terror and analyses the effect of charity donations on violence in Pakistan, detecting a positive effect. My contribution to this literature lies in offering evidence of a com- plementarity in producing attacks between Zakat donations and recruitment and identifying the supply effect of terror, through increased activities by extremist organizations.

This paper also joins a literature on the determinants of terrorism, which has highlighted the lack of a link with poverty both from a cross-country perspective (Abadie(2006), Krueger and Maleˇckov´a(2009)) and a within-country focus (Krueger and Maleckova(2002),Benmelech and Berrebi (2007),Krueger (2008), Blair et al. (2013)). My results are in line with this literature, given that the increase in attacks is entirely due to an increase in the supply of terrorist attacks by organizations, rather than changes in the local labour supply or poverty. These findings are also connected the literature on income shocks and conflict, that documented this link both through a series of cross-country studies (Miguel et al. (2004), Burke et al. (2009), Miguel and Satyanath (2011),Besley and Persson (2011), Bazzi and Blattman (2014)) and a detailed collection of within-country analysis and local-level shocks (Dube and Vargas(2013),Nunn and Qian (2014),Crost et al. (2014),Berman et al.(2017)). I document a specific channel through which income shocks may generate conflict: an increase in the funding of violent actors, who increase their engagement in recruitment and mobilization.

Figure 1: Terrorist Attacks over Time

0500100015002000 Number of a Terrorist Attacks in PK

05000100001500020000Number of a Terrorist Attacks

2000 2005 2010 2015

Year World

0500100015002000 Number of a Terrorist Attacks in PK

05000100001500020000Number of a Terrorist Attacks

2000 2005 2010 2015

Year

World Pakistan

Notes: The left panel shows the evolution in the number of terrorist attacks all over the World between 2000 and 2015, while the right panel includes also the number of attacks taking place in Pakistan (reported on the right y-axis). In both cases I am using the Global Terrorism Database GTD from the National Consortium for the Study of Terrorism and Responses to Terrorism.

In Section 2, I offer some institutional aspects of the Zakat levy, and the relation between government-collected Zakat and private donations with the international price of silver. Section 3 investigates the reduced-form evidence on Zakat donations and terrorism, through a lead- and-lag analysis and difference-in-difference estimation along different margins (probability of attack, number of attacks, killed and wounded). In Section 4, I describe two key methodological

(8)

contributions. First, the estimation of global terrorist recruitment through the machine-learning algorithm, which permits to verify that the effect of donations on attacks is much stronger in period of intense recruitment. Second, a novel variation to dissect the demand from the supply of terrorist attacks and estimate the elasticity of terror attacks to financing. In Section 5, I describe the Eid Adha placebo and some additional robustness checks. Finally, Section 6 reports some concluding remarks.

2 Institutional Features

In this section I present the relation between the Zakat donation and silver, and how this affects the financing of charities and terrorist organizations. First, I describe the specifics on how the government-run Zakat scheme works, its relation to silver prices and present a religious map of Pakistan to distinguish Sunni and non-Sunni cities.

Second, I offer three stylized facts offering a first stage to this experiment: 1) I show that individual donations from Sunni-majority areas increase in the price of silver; 2) I verify that individual receptions in Sunni-majority areas decline in the price of silver; 3) I verify that the operations of Pakistani charities (measured through their balance sheets) are highly correlated with the price of silver at the beginning of Ramadan.

Overall, these stylized facts are in line with the underlying hypothesis: in periods of high silver prices there is an increase in charity donations in Sunni-majority areas, which do not translate in more receptions because some of these funds are funnelled to terrorist groups.

2.1 Zakat and Silver Prices

The Zakat donation is one of the five pillars of Islam and part of Sharia law. As Ramadan begins, Muslim are required by this religious obligation to donate to the poorest and vulnerable, in exchange for a religious regeneration of their wealth. While this donation is left as an individual contribution in most countries, Malaysia, Saudi Arabia and Pakistan present a government-run scheme to collect and allocate these resources.

However, Pakistan offers a unique system to manage Zakat, which leads to a useful natural experiment. In 1981, a conservative-leaning government introduced the mandatory Zakat pay- ment to the state.8 This was executed through a Sharia-compliant obligation corresponding to a 2.5% levy on those deposit accounts above an eligibility threshold (Nisab-i-Zakat ). The defi- nition of such threshold is grounded in the local interpretations of the Sharia law by Pakistani scholars and is defined by the international price of silver. As a result, the yearly threshold is obtained by multiplying the price of silver on the day of the threshold announcement times 612.32 grams (52 tolas, a local measurement unit).

Two key characteristics in the implementation of this levy play an important role. First, the local authorities (State Bank of Pakistan and Ministry of Religious Affairs) announce the actual threshold only 2 days before the collection. This implies that the international price of silver in

8Refer to the Zakat and Ushr Ordinance, 1980, available at http://www.zakat.gop.pk/system/files/

zakatushr1980.pdf. For a historical review, refer toNasr(2004).

(9)

the announcement day determines the threshold and, consequently, the tax base and revenue collection. Figure 2 shows a correlation between the Zakat threshold and the international price of silver in the day of the announcement, exhibiting a correlation of 0.98. The left panel of Figure 3 reports both the country-wide government collection of Zakat revenue and, in the right panel, the high and negative correlation of such revenue with silver prices, -0.86. Finally, Table 1 presents some summary statistics on the Zakat revenue: it is high but not enormous (equivalent to an average of 363 million real USD per year) and presents a significant time-series volatility. Finally, Figure 4 shows that the exact value of the threshold and, hence, the revenue and donations may be hard to predict ex ante, given that silver is one of the most volatile metallic commodities. Figure 4 offers two plots in this direction. The left-panel compares the quarterly volatility in the price of silver (blue, full line) and gold (red, dashed line) for the past 15 years and shows that silver is 43% more volatile than gold. The right-panel offers a long-term perspective on silver volatility, showing its large swings between 1980 and 2015.

Second, Pakistan is an Islamic Republic professing the Sunni school of Islam, closer in its interpretation to Saudi Arabia and 76% of Pakistanis belong to this sect. The second largest group adheres to the Shia school of Islam (closer to the Iran interpretation), which accounts for 19% of the country. The remaining 5% is composed by Hindus, Christians, Animists and other smaller groups. Figure 5 reports a religious map published by the Gulf 2000 - Columbia University project, displaying the geographic distribution of these religious groups. I extensively use this map to define cities that are affected by the silver-related levy from cities that are not.

This is very important, because only Sunni Muslim are subject to the levy and, as a result, I am able to classify whether a city belongs to the treatment or control group through their religious majority. It is important to highlight that while extremely informative, the map may not be perfect and is based on a combination of census data, historical maps and additional material. As a result, there may be a measurement error in the definition of cities. While I expect this error not to be correlated with the treatment, it is important to highlight that it makes my estimates a lower bound, as it shrinks the main effect to toward zero.

Figure 2: Zakat Threshold and the International Price of Silver

0200004000060000Threshold in PKR

0 10 20 30 40

International Price of Silver in USD per Ounce − Threshold Announcement Day

Notes: This figures reports a scatterplot between the Zakat Threshold in Pakistani Rupees (PKR), on the y-axis, and the International Price of Silver per Ounce at the announcement day, x-axis. The correlation between the two is 0.98***.

(10)

Figure 3: Zakat Revenue over Time and Silver Prices

05000100001500020000Real Zakat Revenue − Million PKR

1980 1990 2000 2010

Year

88.599.510Real Zakat Revenue ? Ln Million PKR

1 2 3 4

Price of Silver − Ln USD

Notes: The left panel shows the evolution in the Zakat Revenue collected by the Pakistani Government between 1981 and 2015 in millions of real PKR. The right panel correlates the revenue in natural logarithm of million PKR with the international price of silver in the day of the announcement in the natural logarithm of USD. These two variables are correlated -0.86***.

Figure 4: The Volatility in Silver and Gold Prices

0.01.02.03.04Volatility per Quarter

1/1/2000 1/1/2005 1/1/2010 1/1/2015

Date

Silver Gold

.01.02.03.04Volatility per Quarter

1/1/1980 1/1/1985 1/1/1990 1/1/1995 1/1/2000 1/1/2005 1/1/2010 1/1/2015 Date

Notes: This left-panel picture compares the volatility in the price of silver and gold in a given quarter between 2000 and 2015.

The volatility is defined as the standard deviation of the daily difference in the natural logarithm of silver prices in a quarter.

The average volatility of both commodities is 0.0154 and silver is 43% less volatile than gold, the difference is -0.0067***. The right-panel reports the same measure of volatility, focusing on silver, between 1980 and 2015.

Table 1: Summary Statistics on Zakat Collection

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Variable Obs. Mean S.D. Min Max

Real Zakat in Mill PKR 35 9,924 3,760 3,134 17,091 Real Zakat in Mill PPP USD 35 363.83 282.89 30.84 904.83

Notes: This table reports the summary statistics on Zakat collection by the central government between 1981 and 2015. The variables are expressed in real million PKR for the first variable and real million of PPP United States Dollar (USD) for the second variable. Column (1) counts the number of observations, (2) the standard deviation, (3) and (4) reports the minimum and maximum collection.

(11)

Figure 5: A Religious Map of Pakistan

Notes: The map shows the geographic distribution of different religious groups in Pakistan and is elaborated by Dr Michael Izady through the Gulf 2000 - Columbia University project. Different colours describe the presence of different religious groups.

Bright green areas report cities that exhibit a Sunni-majority, dark green cities with Shia-majority, Purple with Hindu majority and Blue with Christian majority. An area filled with full-body colour implies an area of high population density, while an area with shaded colour indicates low density. Mixed areas are reported with multi-colour horizontal lines.

2.2 Individual Donations and Charities

In this section, I verify through individual data that silver prices affect three categories of agents:

donors, recipients and charities. I find that when silver prices are high (low government revenue), the following events take place: individual donations increase, individual receptions decline and charities receive more funds. This story is consistent with some charities funnelling donations towards terrorist groups. It is important to note that because I focus on the differential effect of silver prices between Sunni and non-Sunni majority areas, this nets out the possible increase in donations due to a wealth effect of higher silver prices. In fact, in case this effect exists, it is likely to affect similarly both Sunni and non-Sunni individuals.

The “Pakistan Social And Living Standards Measurement Survey” (PSLM) conducted by the Pakistan Bureau of Statistics offers information on individual donations and receptions of Zakat. This is a repeated cross-section that reports several economic indicators for more than 80,000 individuals across the 30 divisions all over Pakistan for five years (2005, 2007, 2010, 2011 and 2013). Divisions are second-order administrative units in Pakistan, equivalent to counties in the United States, and there are 30 all over Pakistan. The survey is stratified at the level of division, as a result I conduct the rest of the analysis concerning charity donations in this section and in section 4.2 at such higher level of geographic aggregation.

The survey asks the amount that an individual donates to and receives from Zakat, making this dataset ideal for our analysis. Because Zakat is a sensitive topic in Pakistan, the response rate is not high: only 5,485 (6.8%) provide information on their Zakat donation and 1,009 (1.3%) on the reception. However, there are enough observations to verify how the donations and receptions respond to silver prices in Sunni-majority divisions through a difference-in- difference model. For this reason I run the following regression

ln Zakatidt = a1 Silvert× Sunnid+ a2Incomeidt+ ιd+ ιt+ uidt (1)

(12)

in which the Zakat donated or received by individual i in division d at time t is regressed over an interaction between the standardized international price of silver and a dummy identifying Sunni-majority divisions, Silvert×Sunnid, a control for the income of the individual, Incomeidt, and then division and time fixed effects, ιd and ιt. Table 3 reports the results of equation (2), both for the Zakat donations in columns (1) and (2) and the receptions in (3) and (4). Three interesting results emerge from these regressions. The first two columns highlight that when silver prices are one standard deviation higher, then Zakat donations increase by 7-9% in Sunni- majority divisions. On the contrary, the last two columns show that the received Zakat declines by 12-14% when silver is one standard deviation above the average price in Sunni-majority divisions. Finally, I verify that people with a higher income offer more Zakat donations (one percent higher income corresponds to 0.160 percent more donations), while individuals with a lower income register a higher Zakat received (one percent lower income delivers 0.067 percent higher receptions).

Table 2: Zakat Donations, Receptions and Silver

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Variables Zakat Donated Zakat Received

Ln(PKRs) Ln(PKRs)

Silvert× Sunnid 0.0753** 0.0940** -0.121* -0.139*

(0.0371) (0.0396) (0.0653) (0.0742)

Ln Yearly Income 0.160*** -0.0667**

(0.0196) (0.0292)

Observations 5467 5467 1009 1009

Division FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Adj. R sq. 0.139 0.187 0.288 0.351

Mean Dep. Var. 8.043 8.043 8.818 8.818 S.D. Dep. Var. 1.330 1.330 1.333 1.333

Notes: This table presents ordinary least-squares (OLS) estimates, where the unit of observation is a individual i in division d in year t. Division and year fixed effects are present in all columns and standard errors are clustered at household level. The dependent variable in columns (1) and (2) is the natural logarithm of the Zakat donated by an individual, while in columns (3) and (4) is the Zakat received by an individual. This is regressed over an interaction between the international price of silver at the announcement of the Zakat threshold, Silvert, and a dummy taking unit value for Sunni-majority districts, Sunnid. In all columns the price of silver is standardized, hence I subtract the mean across all periods and divide by the standard deviation. The row Adj. R sq. shows the adjusted R2 of these regressions, and the next two rows show the mean and standard deviation (S.D.) of the dependent variable, respectively. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively.

In addition to the previous test, I offer additional evidence on the first stage linking a higher silver-induced tax and donations. If information on bank deposits was available, then I could offer a regression discontinuity design and show that individuals marginally affected by changes in the tax threshold modify their donations. Unfortunately, the PSLM does not collect data on deposits, savings or wealth in general. As a result, I employ a different method. The mean income per household in the survey is roughly 240,000 Pakistani Rupees (PKR), corresponding to 2,100 United States Dollars (USD), and the average threshold between 2005 and 2013 is approximately 25,000 PKRs (corresponding to 215.93 USD). As a result, it is likely that the individuals affected by changes in silver prices are likely to be those with low-to-medium savings

(13)

and, hence, not the extreme of the income distributions. Poor individuals are likely not to have a bank account, or not save enough to be eligible to pay the tax; while individuals with a very high income are always taxed regardless of the price of silver.

Therefore, I use the information on income and study how donations respond across different income quartiles by interacting the coefficient Silvert× Sunnid in equation (1) with a series of dummies for each income quartile. Figure 6 shows how individuals respond to a one standard deviation increase in silver prices depending on their income quartile and whether they are in a Sunni or non-Sunni division. The red dashed line shows that individuals living in non-Sunni areas do not change their donations depending on the price of silver, independently of their income. This is consistent with the fact that non-Sunni are not affected by the bank tax and, hence, do not change their charity behaviour based on silver. On the contrary, the full blue line shows that individuals living in Sunni-majority cities react always positively to changes in the price of silver, with the second and third quartile being those with the strongest increases in charity donations: in these cases a one-standard deviation increase in silver, generates on aver- age a 20% increase in donations by these two groups. As expected, the effects are significantly smaller and marginally insignificant for individuals living in the first and forth quartile: poor individuals may never be taxed, while richer individuals may donate regardless of the tax.

Regarding the role of charities in Pakistan, it is important to clarify that while there are some excellent institutions that conduct admirable work and reach out to poor and vulnerable individuals, others diverge from this scenario. In fact, several charities have been directly associated to terrorist groups over the past decade. For example, this link was very direct for Hafiz Saeed, who was one of the founder of an important terrorist group (Lashkar-e-Taiba) and, at the same time, headed a charitable foundation in Pakistan until February 2018.9 Similarly, the terrorist group Jihad bi al-Saif has been linked to the the charity Tablighis Jamaat.10 Some groups have created their own charities in order to raise their financial capacity. This was the case of Harkat-ul-Mujahedeen, led by Maulana Fazlur Rehman Khalil, and Jammat-ul- Furqan, led by Maulana Abdullah Shah Mazhar, two banned militant outfits linked to the TTP and al Qaeda, who created charitable foundations, under the new names Ansar-ul-Umma and Tehreek-e-Ghalba Islam, to boost their funding.11

Once the existence of a link between charities and terrorist groups has been clarifying, it is necessary to investigate the relation between silver prices and charitable donations requires data on charities funding. This is a difficult task, given that Pakistani charities are not obliged by law to publish annual reports and, as a result, data access is particularly challenging. In order to provide some evidence in line with the mechanism, I digitized the annual reports of one of the largest Pakistani charities (the Cancer Hospital charity) for all years it is publicly available (2000 to 2016). In addition to this I also digitized the balance sheets of other 20

9Refer to this Reuters articlehttps://www.reuters.com/article/us-pakistan-militants-financing/

pakistan-bans-charities-linked-to-founder-of-militant-group-idUSKCN1FY1SN

10Refer to this Stratfor - WorldView article https://worldview.stratfor.com/article/

tablighi-jamaat-indirect-line-terrorism

11Refer to this Global Ecco articlehttps://globalecco.org/it/pakistan-money-for-terror

(14)

charities.12 Figure 7 presents two scatterplots: in the first, I correlate the annual funding of the the Cancer Hospital charity to the international price of silver at the threshold announcement;

in the second, first I demean the charity funding, by regressing their natural logarithm on a charity fixed effect, then correlate this residual with the price of silver. In both cases the correlation is positive, quantitatively large and statistically different from zero. While I do not claim that such charities are involved in any activities related to terrorist organizations, this data is consistent with the fact that Sunni Muslims increase their charity donations in periods of low government Zakat, given by high silver prices, and that some of this funding (that reaches other charities) may finance terrorist organizations.

Figure 6: Heterogeneous Effect of Silver by Income Quartile

−.2−.10.1.2.31 St. Dev of Silver on Ln Zakat Donation

1 2 3 4

Income Quartile

Non−Sunni Sunni

Notes: This picture reports the coefficients of a regression estimating the effect of a one standard deviation increase in silver prices on Zakat donations of individuals living in Sunni and non-Sunni cities, depending on their income quartile. The model is expressed by equation (1) and the standard errors are clustered at household level. The red and dashed line shows the coefficient for individuals living in non-Sunni majority cities, while the blue and full line shows the coefficients for individuals living in Sunni-majority cities.

Figure 7: Charity Donations and Silver

19202122Charity Funding in Ln PKR

1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5

Price of Silver − Ln USD

−3−2−1012Residuals − Charity Funding in Ln PKR

1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5

Price of Silver − Ln USD

Notes: The left panel shows a scatterplot between the funding of the Cancer Hospital measured in log PKR and the international price of silver at the threshold announcement in ln USD. The right panel reports a scatter between the residuals of a regression of the log PKR donated to 21 charities on the charity fixed effect and the international price of silver at the threshold announcement in log USD. The correlations are respectively 0.85*** and 0.39***.

12The charities presented in Figure 5 are Aurat Foundation, Awaz Foundation, CARE Foundation, Can- cer Hospital, Child Aid, Durul Sukun Foundation, EHSAAS Trust, Indus Hospital, LRBT Foundation, Marie Adelaide Leprosy Centre, Pukar Foundation, Roshni Homes, SHARP Foundation, Sahara Foundation, Sus- tainable Development Institute, Sustainable Social Development Foundation, The Citizens Foundation, Trust Democratic Education Foundation and the Zindagi Trust.

(15)

3 Terrorism Financing and Attacks

3.1 Data

In order to study the effect of charity donations on terrorist attacks, I build a panel that reports the terrorist attacks recorded in 1,545 cities over 96 quarter-years between 1992 and 2015. The Global Terrorism Database (GTD) published by the National Consortium for the Study of Terrorism and Responses to Terrorism contains the universe of terrorist attacks in Pakistan, that gives around 12,000 events and exceeds 4,600 periods in which a city is hit by at least one attack. In order to make the panel reliable and usable, I harmonized the names of the cities that could present multiple spellings (given the transliteration from Urdu to English) and coded each city with a dummy for whether they are in a Sunni-majority area, using the map presented in Figure 5.

The database contains information on whether a terrorist attack took place, as well as the number of attacks and attack-related killed and wounded. It also reports the specific type of each attack (e.g. Bombing Explosion, Assassination, Armed Assault, Infrastructure Attack, et cetera) and the corresponding number of individuals that were killed and wounded. This dataset is joined with information on specific quarters in which Ramadan took place in every year and combined with information on the the international price of silver at the announcement day of every Zakat payment.

Table 3 reports the summary statistics for the main variables in each dataset. Panel A presents four variables: a dummy that takes unit value whenever a city is hit by at least one terrorist attack in a quarter-year, Probability of Attack, and then the number of Attacks, Killed and Wounded. The first variable shows that the unconditional probability of a terrorist attack in a quarter-year in Pakistan is 3.1%, with a very high standard deviation given that more than 50% of Pakistani cities receive only one attack between 1992 and 2015. Similarly the variables number of attacks, killed and wounded present a similar pattern: very low means, high standard deviations and very high maxima. Panel B shows that 53.4% of Pakistani cities are coded as being Sunni-majority, this was expected given that 76% of the local population professes the Sunni school of Islam. It also leads to two important considerations: 1) there are several areas in which Sunnis are present but not majority (mixed with Shias, Hindus, Christians and Animists); 2) this implies the existence of a geographic concentration of Sunnis in particular cities over others. Finally, Panel C reports statistics on the international price of silver per ounce in USD, this dataset is widely available through online platforms (e.g. Bloomberg, et cetera). For every year I only focus on the price of silver at the threshold announcement and report it for all other quarters. The mean price of silver is 10.829 USD, with a very high standard deviation which imply a strong volatility in silver prices, as clarified by the minimum and maximum price of this commodity that ranges between 3.64 and 39.892 USD.

(16)

Table 3: Summary Statistics on Attacks, Cities and Silver

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

Variable Obs. Mean S.D. Min Max

Panel A - Terrorist Attacks

Probability of Attack 148,320 0.031 0.174 0 1 Number of Attacks 148,320 0.081 1.363 0 211 Number of Killed 148,320 0.138 2.556 0 222 Number of Wounded 148,320 0.232 4.799 0 452

Panel B - Sunni-Majority Cities

Sunnic 1,545 0.534 0.499 0 1

Panel C - International Price of Silver

Silvert 96 10.829 8.814 3.64 39.892

Notes: This table presents the summary statistics for the three databases used in this section: panel A reports this for the number of terrorist attacks; panel B for the classification of cities into being Sunni-majority with a dummy and panel C summarizes data on the international price of silver at the announcement of the Zakat threshold. Column (2) reports the number of observations, Columns (3) and (4) the mean and standard deviation each variable, while Columns (5) and (6) indicate the minimum and maximum.

3.2 Empirical Model and Results

The empirical analysis proceeds in two steps. First, I study whether Sunni-majority and non Sunni-majority cities evolve on different trends around the Ramadan period and, as a result, I offer a lead-and-lag analysis. Because I find that there is an increase in terrorist attacks only in the quarter in which the financing takes place (Ramadan) and the following, I focus on these two and proceed with a classic difference-in-difference estimator.

The following empirical model presents the first step

T errorct=

2

X

t=0

ctSunnic× Qt+

2

X

t=−1

dtSunnic× Silvert× Qt+ ιc+ ιt+ εct (2) equation (3) regresses a terror variable in city c at quarter-year t, T errorct (the probability of an attack or the number of attacks), over a set of quarter-year fixed effects in the quarter before Ramadan (-1), the Ramadan quarter (0) and subsequent quarters (1 and 2), Qt, interacted with the dummy coding Sunni-majority cities, Sunnic, and then the same two variables interacted again with the standardized price of silver at the threshold announcement, Silvert.

The coefficients reported by ctverify the differential evolution between Sunni-majority cities (treated) and non Sunni-majority cities (control) when the price of silver is at its average value, while the coefficients dt embody this differential effect when the price of silver is one standard deviation above the mean. This is the treatment of the paper: high silver prices imply low government Zakat revenue and high charity donations, which may finance terrorist organizations. Note that because the Ramadan takes place in every year, I am unable to include dummies going back more than one period or going forward more than two periods, as they would be collinear with the previous or following Ramadan.

Figure 6 reports the results of this lead-and-lag analysis. It clarifies that in periods of silver prices at the mean (blue dashed line), there is no statistical difference between Sunni-

(17)

majority and non Sunni-majority cities, neither in the probability of a terrorist attack nor in the number of attacks (see Appendix B for the 95% confidence intervals). The red solid line displays the results when silver prices are one standard deviation above the mean. While there is no statistical difference in the quarter before Ramadan, there is a spike in both the probability of a terror attack and the number of terrorist attacks at Ramadan. This effect lasts also for the quarter following Ramadan and disappears two quarters afterwards. It is important to note that such spike at Ramadan is statistically significant only for those two quarters (as Appendix B clarifies) and is quantitatively large: a 1% higher probability of terror attacks (baseline probability is 3.14%) or 0.8% higher number of terrorist attacks.

Given that the effect is concentrated only in two quarters, I define a dummy variable that takes unit value for each quarter of a year that contains Ramadan and the subsequent quarter, Ramadant, and proceed with a difference-in-difference model

T errorct = f1Sunnic× Silvert+ f2Sunnic× Ramadant+

+f3Sunnic× Silvert× Ramadant+ ιc+ ιt+ εct (3) in which the terror variable observed in city c at time t, T errorct, is regressed over an inter- action between the Sunni-majority dummy, Sunnic, and the price of silver at the threshold announcement, Silvert; an interaction between Sunnic and Ramadant, and finally, a triple interaction between these three variables. The coefficient f1 reports the effect of silver prices on Sunni-majority cities in any period, f2 reports the average effect of silver in Sunni-majority areas only at Ramadan time, while f3 documents the effect of a one standard deviation increase in silver prices above the mean at Ramadan time.

Figure 6: Terrorist Attacks, Zakat and Silver Prices

0.002.004.006.008.01Probability of a Terrorist Attack

−1 0 1 2

Quarter

Silver Price − Mean Silver Price − 1 SD Higher

0.002.004.006.008Ln Number of a Terrorist Attacks

−1 0 1 2

Quarter

Silver Price − Mean Silver Price − 1 SD Higher

Notes: Both panel show the differential evolution in the probability of a terrorist attack (left panel) and ln number of terrorist attacks (right panel) between Sunni-majority cities and non Sunni-majority cities. The dashed blue line reports the difference when the price of silver is at its mean value, while the red solid line when it is one standard deviation above the mean. Appendix B contains the same figures with the 95% confidence interval and the regression results.

Table 4 reports the results of equation (4) for the probability of a terror attack in column (1), the natural logarithm of the number of terror attacks (column (2)), the number of terror-related killed individuals (column (3)) and wounded individuals (column (4)). In all cases the price of silver does not seem to exert a differential effect on the probability of a terrorist attack in Sunni- majority cities, as I cannot reject a zero effect for the variable Sunnic× Silvert in any column.

(18)

The second coefficient highlights that there is an increase in the probability of a terrorist attack when Ramadan arrives in Sunni-majority cities and the price of silver is at its mean. This effect is statistically different from zero, though quantitatively not particularly large: this corresponds to a 10% increase on the 3.14% baseline probability. While this extensive margin seems to be not irrelevant, a zero cannot be rejected for the extensive margin of terrorist attacks (number of attacks, killed and wounded). The final row shows that there is a large increase in terrorist activities when Ramadan arrives in Sunni-majority cities and the price of silver is one standard deviation above its mean. The quantitative effect is large: the increase in the probability of a terrorist attack is overall 1% and corresponds to a 33% higher probability of an attack. The effect is similar for the number of attacks, though quantitatively smaller, with an increase of 20%.

Table 4: Terrorist Attacks, Sunni Cities and Silver

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Variables Terror Attacks Killed Wounded

Dummy Ln(1+N) Ln(1+N) Ln(1+N) Sunnic × Silvert 0.00115 0.00216 -0.000973 -0.00158 (0.00296) (0.00420) (0.00432) (0.00476) Sunnic × Ramadant 0.00324** 0.00149 0.000269 0.000886 (0.00155) (0.00145) (0.00192) (0.00205) Sunnic × Silvert × 0.00727*** 0.00471** 0.00384 0.00476*

Ramadant (0.00219) (0.00196) (0.00276) (0.00283)

City FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Quarter-Year FE Yes Yes Yes Yes

Obs. 148320 148320 148320 148320

Adj. R sq. 0.183 0.280 0.211 0.213

Mean Dep. Var. 0.0314 0.0311 0.0270 0.0305

S.D. Dep. Var. 0.175 0.198 0.237 0.277

Notes: This table presents ordinary least-squares (OLS) estimates, where the unit of observation is a city c in in quarter-year t. City and Quarter-Year fixed effects are present in all columns and standard errors are clustered at city-level. The dependent variables are: the probability of a terror attack in Column (1), Terror Dummy; the natural logarithm of the number of terrorist attacks in Column (2), Attacks Ln(1 + N ); the natural logarithm of the number of terrorist-related killed individuals in Column (3), Killed Ln(1 + N ); the natural logarithm of the number of terrorist-related wounded individuals in Column (4), Wounded Ln(1 + N ).

These are regressed over a dummy taking unit value in Sunni-majority cities, Sunnic; the price of silver at the announcement of the Zakat threshold, Silvert; a dummy taking unit value for the quarter in which Ramadan takes place and the following quarter, Ramadant. In order to simplify the interpretation of the coefficients, the price of silver is standardized, hence I subtract the mean across all periods and divide by the standard deviation. The row Adj. R sq. shows the adjusted R2of these regressions, and the next two rows show the mean and standard deviation of the dependent variable, respectively. ***, ** and * indicate significance at the 1%, 5% and 10% level, respectively.

The last two variables, number of killed and wounded, present much noisier results. This is due to the fact that often the number of killed and wounded individuals is approximate, not reported or higher than zero only for the top 5% of the distribution. For this reason, in Table 4 and the other tables, the results on killed and wounded are typically positive, but either marginally significant or insignificant. In fact, the killed variable presents a positive sign and a coefficient in line with the previous result: an increase in the baseline probability of 15%, however its coefficient is not statistically different from zero. Similarly, the number of wounded individuals appears to increase by a significant magnitude with respect to the baseline (19%), though is statistically different from zero only at a 10% significance level.

Section 5 offers some additional tests, that refine the results of Table 4. In 5.1 I replicate the same results of equation (4) but for an alternative Islamic celebration, Eid Adha, and

(19)

compute the price of silver traded two days before this celebration. In section 5.2, I address two additional robustness checks. First, I control for city-specific seasonality by introducing a city-quarter fixed effect, that nets out local confounding factors (e.g. local agricultural cycle, local rain season, et cetera). Second, I control for the fact that different Pakistani states may evolve on different trend (e.g. income, inflation, et cetera) and I can exclude such state-year common shocks through fixed effects.

Finally I analyse the effect of silver on the different types of attacks, verifying which ones increase around Ramadan. While this may be useful in understanding the patterns behind the attacks, also in this case the coding of attacks may not be perfect and lead to non trivial noise.

For example the classification of an attack as “bombing”, “assassination” or “infrastructure control” may be arbitrary and create noise that is reflected in the estimates. In Table 5 I show those that report statistically different effects, while in Appendix C I report those that are not.

Column (1) and (4) show respectively the effect on the probability of a bombing attack and the number of bombing attacks. Both of these respond positively, significantly and with large quantitative effects (31% and 18%). Columns (2) and (5) present results on the probability of assassinations and the number of assassination attacks, while the first is not statistically different from zero, the second presents a statistically detectable effect only for the average price of silver (the one standard deviation effect is not significant). In this case the sign is positive, significant at 10% and quantitatively large (21% of the baseline). Finally, columns (3) and (6) study the response respectively along the probability and number of unarmed attacks.

While only the former is significant and only for the average price of silver, nevertheless the magnitude is very large in terms of its baseline mean (a 136% increase).13

Table 5: Type of Terrorist Attack and Silver

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

Variables Bombing Assassination Unarmed Bombing Assassination Unarmed

Dummy Dummy Dummy Ln(1+N) Ln(1+N) Ln(1+N)

Sunnic × 0.00196 0.000645 0.000111 0.00211 0.000162 0.00006 Silvert (0.00258) (0.000764) (9.63e-05) (0.00348) (0.000731) (0.00006) Sunnic × 0.00201 0.000666 0.000221* 0.000710 0.000706* 0.000006 Ramadant (0.00124) (0.000539) (0.000120) (0.00118) (0.000413) (0.000101) Sunnic × 0.00461*** 0.000644 -0.000177 0.00296* 0.000785 -0.000006 Silvert × (0.00173) (0.000755) (0.000166) (0.00157) (0.000631) (0.000124) Ramadant

City, Q-Y FE Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes

Obs. 148320 148320 148320 148320 148320 148320

Adj. R sq. 0.154 0.114 0.0115 0.214 0.216 0.0122

Mean Dep. Var. 0.0210 0.00386 0.000162 0.0201 0.00331 0.000134

S.D. Dep. Var. 0.144 0.0620 0.0127 0.153 0.0608 0.0134

Notes: This table presents ordinary least-squares (OLS) estimates, where the unit of observation is a city c in in quarter-year t. City and Quarter-Year fixed effects are present in all columns and standard errors are clustered at city-level. The dependent variables are: the probability of a terror attack through bombing in Column (1), Bombing Dummy; the probability of a terror attack through an assassination in Column (2), Assassination Dummy; the probability of an unarmed terror attack in Column (3), Unarmed Dummy; columns (4), (5) and (6) report the the natural logarithm of the number of each type of terrorist attack,

13The GTD database describes unarmed attacks as: “An attack whose primary objective is to cause physical harm or death directly to human beings by any means other than explosive, firearm, incendiary, or sharp instrument (knife, etc.). Attacks involving chemical, biological or radiological weapons are considered unarmed assaults”. Refer tohttps://www.start.umd.edu/gtd/downloads/Codebook.pdf.

References

Related documents

spårbarhet av resurser i leverantörskedjan, ekonomiskt stöd för att minska miljörelaterade risker, riktlinjer för hur företag kan agera för att minska miljöriskerna,

This project focuses on the possible impact of (collaborative and non-collaborative) R&D grants on technological and industrial diversification in regions, while controlling

Analysen visar också att FoU-bidrag med krav på samverkan i högre grad än när det inte är ett krav, ökar regioners benägenhet att diversifiera till nya branscher och

a) Inom den regionala utvecklingen betonas allt oftare betydelsen av de kvalitativa faktorerna och kunnandet. En kvalitativ faktor är samarbetet mellan de olika

• Utbildningsnivåerna i Sveriges FA-regioner varierar kraftigt. I Stockholm har 46 procent av de sysselsatta eftergymnasial utbildning, medan samma andel i Dorotea endast

I dag uppgår denna del av befolkningen till knappt 4 200 personer och år 2030 beräknas det finnas drygt 4 800 personer i Gällivare kommun som är 65 år eller äldre i

Denna förenkling innebär att den nuvarande statistiken över nystartade företag inom ramen för den internationella rapporteringen till Eurostat även kan bilda underlag för

DIN representerar Tyskland i ISO och CEN, och har en permanent plats i ISO:s råd. Det ger dem en bra position för att påverka strategiska frågor inom den internationella