• No results found

Knock Out Power Options in Foreign Exchange Markets

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Knock Out Power Options in Foreign Exchange Markets"

Copied!
67
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

U.U.D.M. Project Report 2014:10

Examensarbete i matematik, 30 hp Handledare och examinator: Johan Tysk Maj 2014

Department of Mathematics

Knock Out Power Options in Foreign Exchange Markets

Tomé Eduardo Sicuaio

(2)
(3)

UPPSALA UNIVERSITET

Matematiska Institutionen

MASTER’S THESIS

KNOCK OUT POWER OPTIONS IN FOREIGN EXCHANGE MARKETS

COURSE: DEGREE PROJECT E IN MATHEMATICS

Student’s name: Sicuaio, Tom´e Eduardo Supervisor: Prof. Johan Tysk

tomeeduardosicuaio@uem.mz Civic registration number: 790603-P112

(4)
(5)

Acknowledgements

I would like to express my sincere thanks to Prof. Johan Tysk for his helpful comments, suggestions and for the continuous support in achieving this work. I thank as well the Mathematics Department of Eduardo Mondlane University for the given opportunity to take my masters studies in one of the best Universities in the world. I am also very grateful to International Science Program team for their hospitality. I would also like to express my sincere thanks to my family, friends and loved ones for their continuous love and encouragement.

(6)

Abstract

In recent years, the pressure of governments in maintaining currency parity has led to the break down of quite a few exchange rate mechanisms and has, thus, strengthened the need for companies, in particular, to make foreign exchange hedging decisions in order to avoid erosion of profit margins. This thesis deals with the pricing of Foreign exchange options. The Knock out options and the Power options will be treated in the sense that their payoffs are computed in closed form. We also combine the previous options in order to yield a new financial product. We find an explicit pricing formula for such financial product. Additionally, a new product of First generation exotic options, called Knock out power options, is described and its payoff is computed and compared with the payoff of the Knock out options.

(7)

Contents

Introduction 1

1 Foreign Exchange Options 3

1.1 Foreign Exchange Options Overview . . . 3

1.2 Exchange Rate Dynamics . . . 3

1.3 Pricing Foreign Exchange Options . . . 7

2 The Joint Distribution of Brownian Motion and its Maximum and Minimum 10 2.1 Reflection Principle . . . 10

2.2 Joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum . . . 11

2.3 Joint density of Brownian motion and its minimum . . . 13

3 Types of Foreign Exchange Options 14 3.1 Power Options . . . 14

3.1.1 Discounted Payoff for Power Options . . . 15

3.1.2 Call and put bets . . . 19

3.2 Knock Out Options . . . 20

3.2.1 Up and Out Options . . . 21

3.2.2 Down and Out Options . . . 25

4 Knock Out Power Options 26 4.1 Discounted payoff valuation . . . 28

4.1.1 Up and out Asymmetric Power call option . . . 28

4.1.2 Up and out Symmetric Power call option . . . 34

4.1.3 Down and out Symmetric Power call option . . . 34

4.1.4 Down and out Asymmetric Power call option . . . 38

4.2 The Greeks for Knock Out Power Options . . . 43

4.3 Static Hedging . . . 46

4.4 Speculation with Knock Out Power Options . . . 49

Conclusion 55

(8)

References 56

(9)

List of Figures

1.1 Spot Exchange Rate . . . 6

2.1 Brownian path with reflection after first passage time . . . 11

3.1 Knock out call option . . . 20

4.1 Asymmetric power call option . . . 27

4.2 Symmetric power call option . . . 27

4.3 Up and out Asymmetric power call options using (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Maturity time) T = 1year, (Strike price) K = 7, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, n = 2. . . . 33

4.4 Discounted payoff of Down and out asymmetric power call and Down and out call (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 4.8, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Maturity time) T = 1year, n = 2 . . 43

4.5 Down and out asymmetric power call options with (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Maturity time) T = 1year, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 4.8, n = 2. . . . 45

4.6 Delta’s comparison and Gamma’s comparison of call options (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, Maturity Time T = 1year, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier)B = 4.8, (Upper barrier)B = 8.4, n = 2. . . . 46

4.7 Replicated payoff function of Up and out asymmetric power call with (Strike price) K = 7, (Leverage coefficient) A = 10, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, (Maturity time) T = 1year, n = 2. 48 4.8 Call options with different Maturities (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Interest rates) rU SD= 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, Strike price K = 7, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, n = 2. . . . 52

4.9 Call options with different Maturities (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 4.8, n = 2. . . . 53

4.10 Call options with different Maturities (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Interest rates) rU SD= 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Strike price) K = 7, n = 2. . . . 53

(10)

List of Tables

4.1 USD appreciation, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 4.8, (interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, (Maturity time) T = 1year, n = 2. . . . 50 4.2 USD depreciation, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 4.8, (Interest rates) rU SD = 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, (Maturity time) T = 1year, n = 2. . . . 51 4.3 USD appreciation, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 4.8, (Interest rates) rU SD= 0.08, rSEK = 0.12, (Volatility) σ = 0.0853, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, (Maturity time) T = 1year, n = 2. . . . 51 4.4 USD appreciations, (Strike price) K = 7, (Lower barrier) B = 5.6, (Interest rates) rU SD=

0.02, rSEK = 0.03, (Volatility) σ = 0.20, (Upper barrier) B = 8.4, (Maturity time) T = 1year, n = 2, DAO - Down and out, UAO - Up and out. . . . 54

(11)

Introduction

Foreign exchange options are of great importance because nowadays are basic ingredients to in- ternational trading, they are many and each with its strategy for hedging.

Wytup [16] in his work describes the Power options whose payoff is just a vanilla option (call or put) raised to the power of n, that is,[(XT−K)+]n, [(K−XT)+]n in the symmetric case; and each term of vanilla option(call or put) is raised to the power of n, that is,(XTn− Kn)+, (Kn− XTn)+ in the asymmetric case. Therefore, we encounter two kinds of Power options, the asymmetric and symmetric.

Furthermore, Wytup [16] also realizes that these options (Power options) are always equipped with high payoff compared to vanilla options. This, limits the risk of a short position even as the option premium for the holder.

This is one of the reasons that motivates speculators to invest in Power options once they request a high option premium. Yet, Wytup [16] and Tompkins [15] discuss hedging possibilities for Power options and they mentions that these options could be hedged using a combination of vanilla op- tions with different strike prices.

Knock out options are Barrier options options whose payoff a Vanilla option if up to maturity time the underlying foreign exchange rate never hits the barrier agreed previously.

The holder of the Knock out option provides protection against the rising of the foreign exchange rate and according to this protection the holder has to pay a premium.

Lipton [7] discusses Barrier options for Foreign exchange options and give different forms of cal- culation of their payoff under risk neutral valuation.

Wytup [16] describes some of advantages and disadvantages of Knock out power options. Ones of the advantages are: Knock out options are cheaper than Vanilla options, Knock out options provide a conditional protection against, for example, stronger USD/weaker SEK, Knock out op- tions give a complete participation, for example, in a weaker USD/stronger SEK. Some of the disadvantages of Knock out options are: The exchange rate may hit the barrier before maturity time and another one is having to pay a premium.

One of the main aims in this thesis is to combine both options, Knock out options and Power options, and forming a new financial product in foreign exchange option which we will call it as Knock out power option. And we will compute its pricing function under risk neutral valuation using different methods.

The thesis consists of five chapters, the first one describe foreign exchange options, and herein,

(12)

we give an overview about foreign exchange options, the dynamics od foreign exchange rate are derived and is also described the pricing partial differential equation (known as Black-Scholes partial differential equation) for foreign exchange options.

In chapter two we describe the joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum and minimum.

For this purpose we discuss the Reflection Principle in which we derive the main probability result that will be used in description of the joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum and minimum.

In the third chapter we describe the types of Foreign exchange options and special attention is given to Knock out options and Power options, and we compute the payoff under risk neutral valuation using different methods.

In the fourth chapter we describe our new financial product, Knock out power option, and also evaluate the payoff under risk neutral of the Down and out asymmetric power call option and Up and out symmetric power call option, using different methods. We also describe the sensitivity’s analysis and we discuss the static hedging for Up and out power call option.

In the last chapter, the fifth, we describe the conclusions about our new financial product, Knock out power option.

(13)

Chapter 1

Foreign Exchange Options

1.1 Foreign Exchange Options Overview

Foreign Exchange Options are of great importance in the business world, allowing international trading over all the world. These options give the holder the right but not the obligation to exchange one currency into another currency at a determined exchange rate on a maturity date previously agreed. Nowadays, trade is just a small part of the domain of foreign exchange exchange market whose leading participants are Commercial Banks, Brokers, The International Monetary Market, Investors, Money Managers, Funds and Central Banks.

The market of foreign exchange options is one of the oldest, by Shamah [12], just because between 9000 to 6000 BCE (Before Common/Current/Christian Era) was seen cattle as well as camels being used as the first and the form of money in exchange options.

The principal characteristic of any foreign exchange option for its holder are those of limited risk and, at the same time, profit potential is unlimited.

Foreign exchange options have been developed to protect companies from some randomness of the exchange rate displacement. They are used by companies as contingent cover because their exposure can lead to unnecessary losses agreement on currency transactions.

1.2 Exchange Rate Dynamics

Before we go deeper in derivation of the Exchange Rate Dynamics let us have a look in some technical concepts which will be need along the section. These definitions can also be found at least on Shreve [13], Neftci [11], Khoshnevisan [5] and Shamah [12].

Definition 1.2.1. An Exchange rate between two currency is the value at which one currency worth to be swapped for another.

Definition 1.2.2. A probability space consists of a sample space Ω, a set of events F and a probability measure P : F → [0, 1]. The sample Ω is a nonempty set, the collection F satisfies the

(14)

following properties 1. ∅ ∈ F ;

2. Whenever A∈ F , its complement Ac∈ F ; 3. whenever A1, A2, . . .∈ F , then their union

n=1

An ∈ F.

In addition the probability measure P is a function that assigns to each element ω ∈ F a number in [0, 1] so that

1. P(Ω) = 1

2. Whenever A1, A2, . . . is a sequence of disjoint events in F, then P( ∪

n=1

An )

= ∑

n=1

P(An).

Definition 1.2.3. Let (Ω,P, F) be a probability space. A real-valued function X defined on Ω with the property that for every Borel subset B of R, the subset of Ω given by {X ∈ B} = {ω ∈ Ω; X(ω)∈ B} is in F, will be called random variable.

Definition 1.2.4. Let X(t) be a collection of random variables, where t is a parameter that runs over an index set T. The collection of random variables in an indexed time set is called stochastic process.

Definition 1.2.5. A Wiener process W is a stochastic process which satisfies the following properties

1. W (0) = 0.

2. The process W has independent increments, i.e. if r < s ≤ t < u then W (u) − W (t) and W (t)− W (r) are independent stochastic variable.

3. For s < t the stochastic variable W (t)− W (s) has Gaussian distribution with mean zero and standard deviation

t− s 4. W has continuous trajectories.

Let X(t) be the Spot Exchange Rate at time t quoted as the quotient between the number of units of the domestic currency and the the number of units of the foreign currency. We will use the notation in Wystup [16] for a quote of foreign exchange rate, as follows, FOR-DOM, which mean that one unit of foreign currency worth FOR-DOM units of domestic currency. For example, in the case of USD-SEK with a spot of 6.3800, this means that one unit of USD worth 6.3800SEK.

We regard that Bf and Bd are bank accounts of the foreign currency and domestic currency,

(15)

respectively. We suppose that under objective probability measure, the Spot Exchange Rate X(t) has a dynamics of a Geometric Brownian Motion [1]

dX = αXXdt + σXXd ¯W , (1.1)

where αX, σX, ¯W are constant drift, constant volatility and scalar Wiener Process, respectively.

We consider that the foreign bank account and the domestic bank account have the following dynamics

dBf = rfBfdt, (1.2)

dBd= rdBddt, (1.3)

where rf, rd are interest rates of the foreign account and domestic account, respectively. According to our exposure Bf units of foreign currency worth X· Bf units in the domestic currency. Thus, we regard that

B¯f = X· Bf, (1.4)

the dynamics of ¯Bf will be obtained applying Ito’s product rule [13] to (1.4), and using the equation (1.1) thus

d ¯Bf = XdBf + BfdX + (dX)(dBf)

= XrfBfdt + XBfαXdt + XBfσXd ¯W + 0

= B¯f(rf + αX)dt + ¯BfσXd ¯W .

We know that the interest rate in the domestic account is rd, so we can write the above equation under martingale measure Q as follows

d ¯Bf = rdB¯fdt + ¯BfσXdW. (1.5) Now, we seek for the dynamics of the spot exchange rate X under martingale measure Q. Using the relation (1.4) we can write X as follows

X = B¯f

Bf. (1.6)

Thus, the Q−dynamics of spot exchange rate X will be obtained applying Ito’s product rule to (1.6) and using relations (1.2) and (1.5) yields

dX = B¯fdBf−1+ Bf−1d ¯Bf + (d ¯Bf)(dBf−1)

= − ¯BfBf−2dBf + Bf−1B¯frddt + Bf−1B¯fσXdW − 0

= − ¯BfBf−2Bfrfdt + Bf−1B¯frddt + Bf−1B¯fσXdW

= −rfXdt + rdXdt + σXXdW

= X(rd− rf)dt + σXXdW.

(16)

Therefore, the dynamics of spot exchange rate under martingale measure is given by

dX = X(rd− rf)dt + σXXdW. (1.7)

Now, we compute the solution to the dynamics of spot exchange rate. Let Z = ln X, applying Ito’s formula we get

dZ = 1

XdX− 1 2

1

X2(dX)2

= (rd− rf)dt + σXdW 1 2σX2dt

= (

rd− rf 1 2σX2

)

dt + σXdW, integrating from t to T yields

Z(T )− Z(t) = (

rd− rf 1 2σX2

)

(T − t) + σX(W (T )− W (t)), we know that Z = ln X , so

ln X(T )− ln X(t) = (

rd− rf 1 2σ2X

)

(T − t) + σX(W (T )− W (t)).

Figure 1.1: Spot Exchange Rate Therefore, solution to the dynamics of spot exchange rate is

X(T ) = X(t)· e(rd−rf12σ2X)(T−t)+σX(W (T )−W (t)), (1.8)

(17)

where (W (T )− W (t)) has a normal distribution with zero mean and standard deviation T − t.

The graph in the Figure 1.1 shows a simulated path, using Monte Carlo method [2], of exchange rate quoted in (USD-SEK) with spot 6.3800, rSEK = 12%, rUSD = 8%, σX = 0.43, Maturity T = 1year.

1.3 Pricing Foreign Exchange Options

Our aim herein, is to derive the pricing equation for foreign exchange options. Similar results can be found on Bj¨ork [1], Jiang[4] and Kwok [6]. Now, regarding the models given in the previous section defined by (1.1), (1.2) and (1.3) and a simple contingent claim of the form Φ(X(T )), where Φ is a contract function.

Let us denote the relative portfolio invested in foreign exchange and the derivative by uB¯f and uF, respectively. The dynamics for the value V of the portfolio is as follows

dV = V (

uB¯f

d ¯Bf

B¯f + uFdF F

)

, (1.9)

where d ¯Bf = ¯Bf(rf + αX)dt + ¯BfσXd ¯W and F = F (t, X(t)) is the pricing function whose dynamics is, applying Ito’s formula and using (1.1), as follows

dF = ∂F

∂tdt + ∂F

∂XdX + 1 2

2F

∂X2(dX)2

= ∂F

∂tdt + (XαXdt + XσXd ¯W )∂F

∂X + 1

2σX2 X22F

∂X2dt

= (

∂F

∂t + XαX∂F

∂X + 1

2σX2X22F

∂X2 )

dt + ∂F

∂XXσXd ¯W

= F αFdt + F σFd ¯W , where

αF =

∂F

∂t + XαX∂X∂F +12σ2XX2 ∂∂X2F2

F and σF =

∂F

∂XX

F . (1.10)

Taking the dynamics of ¯Bf and F to (1.9) and, collecting dt term and d ¯W term yields dV = V(

uB¯f(rf + αX) + uFαF)

dt + V(

uB¯fσX + uFσF) d ¯W . We have to find the relative portfolio in a such way that

{ uB¯fσX + uFσF = 0, uB¯f + uF = 1.

(18)

Solving the above system of linear equations we get the following solution to the system







uF = σX σF − σX

,

uB¯f = σF σF − σX

.

(1.11)

So the d ¯W term of the portfolio value will vanish and we will remain with dV = V(

uB¯f(rf + αX) + uFαF

)dt.

The theory of arbitrage free pricing implies that we must have

uB¯f(rf + αX) + uFαF = rd. (1.12) Substituting (1.11) into (1.12) and multiplying the entire equation by σF − σX we get

(rf + αXF − σXαF = rdF − σX).

Taking (1.10) into the above equation we yield the following partial differential equation,

∂F

∂t + (rd− rf)X∂F

∂X + 1

2σX2X22F

∂X2 − rdF = 0,

the so called Black-Scholes partial differential equation or in a short way the Black-Scholes equa- tion.

Proposition 1.3.1. The pricing function F (t, x) of the claim Φ(XT) solves the boundary value

problem

∂F

∂t + (rd− rf)x∂F∂x + 12σ2xx2 ∂∂x2F2 − rdF = 0, F (T, x) = Φ(x).

Now, we can apply the Feynman-Kac representation theorem, which may be found on Bj¨ork [1], in the above proposition to give us a risk neutral valuation formula.

Proposition 1.3.2. The pricing function has the representation F (t, x) = e−rd(T−t)EQt,x[Φ(XT)], where the Q-dynamics of X are given by

dX(t) = (rd− rf)X(t)dt + σXX(t)dW (t).

(19)

Proof. First we have to apply Ito’s formula to the pricing function F (t, X(t)) as follows

dF (t, X) = (

∂F

∂t + (rd− rf)X∂F

∂X +1

2σX2X22F

∂X2 )

dt + XσX∂F

∂XdW.

Using Proposition 1.3.1 we can write the above equation in the following way dF (t, X) = rdF dt + XσX∂F

∂XdW.

Integrating the above equation in t≤ s ≤ T yields

F (s, X(s))− F (t, X(t)) = rd

s

t

F (τ, X(τ ))dτ + σX

s

t

X(τ )∂F (τ, X(τ ))

∂X dW (τ ).

Furthermore, the process X(τ )∂F (τ,X(τ ))

∂X is integrable and we take the expected value, the stochas- tic integral will be zero and remain the following equation

Et,xQ[F (s, X(s))]− Et,xQ[F (t, X(t))] = rd

s

t

Et,xQ[F (τ, X(τ ))]dτ.

Differentiating the above result with respect to s and integrating from t to T and regarding the initial condition, we get

F (t, x) = e−rd(T−t)Et,xQ[Φ(X(T ))].

(20)

Chapter 2

The Joint Distribution of Brownian

Motion and its Maximum and Minimum

In this section we are going find the joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum or minimum. Similar results, for example, for maximum was discussed in Shreve [13] who has shown the joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum. We also will derive the basic result about Reflection principle which was discussed in Kwok [6] and Shreve [13]. Using reflection principle we are going to derive the basic probability result which will help us to derive the joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum or minimum.

2.1 Reflection Principle

Consider a standard Brownian motion W (t), let ¯M (T ) be the maximum of Brownian motion W (t), suppose that the maximum ¯M (T ) is greater than a positive m, fix a time T and regard that the first passage time , τm, in which the Brownian motion path reach the level m for the first time, τm < T , see Figure 2.1.

Let us define ¯W (t) as the mirror reflection of W (t) at level m between the time interval [τm, T ] and consider ¯W (t) being as follows

W (t) =¯

{ W (t), 0≤ t < τm, 2m− W (t), τm ≤ t < T.

The events {W (T ) < w} and { ¯W (T ) > 2m− w} are equivalents, obviously from τm onward.

For τm ≤ t ≤ T, hold the following equality

W (τ¯ m+ δ)− ¯W (τm) = −(W (τm+ δ)− W (τm)), δ > 0. (2.1) The first passage time , τm, will not affect the Brownian motion at onward time since it depends only on trajectory’s history of Brownian motion, {W (t) : 0 ≤ t ≤ τm}.

(21)

m− w

m− w

τm T t

w m 2m− w M (t)¯

Figure 2.1: Brownian path with reflection after first passage time

The Brownian motion increments in (2.1) have the same distribution, it follows from the strong Markov property of Brownian motion.

The maximum of Brownian motion, ¯M (T ) is greater than m if and only if the first passage time is lesser than T . Now, suppose that W (T )≤ w, then ¯W (T ) ≥ 2m − w and together with (2.1) we obtain

P ( ¯M (T )≥ m, W (T ) ≤ w) = P (τm ≤ T, W (T ) ≤ w)

= P ( ¯W (T ) ≥ 2m − w)

= P (W (T )≥ 2m − w), for all w ≤ m and m > 0.

Proposition 2.1.1. The probability of standard Brownian motion W (t) being lesser than a fixed level w and the Maximum ¯M (t) being greater than a fixed (2m− w) at time T , as described in Figure 2.1, is given by the formula

P ( ¯M (T )≥ m ∧ W (T ) ≤ w) = P (W (T ) ≥ 2m − w), w ≤ m, m > 0. (2.2)

2.2 Joint density of Brownian motion and its maximum

In this section we will follow the theory described in Shreve [13] and Kwok [6]. Let W (t) be a Brownian motion and let us denote by ¯M (T ) = max0≤t≤TW (t) the maximum of Brownian

(22)

motion. We also denote by τm the first passage time at level m > 0. Furthermore, ¯M (T ) ≥ m if and only if the first passage time τm is less or equal to time t.

Thus, in order to find the joint density of ( ¯M (T ), W (T )) we are going to apply the result from Proposition 2.1.1 derived in previous section about reflection principle , so

P ( ¯M (T ) ≥ m ∧ W (T ) ≤ w) = P (W (T ) ≥ 2m − w), w ≤ m, m > 0. (2.3) Regarding the reflection principle equality (2.3) and supposing that fM ,W¯ (m, w) is the joint density of ( ¯M (T ), W (T )) for T > 0 we have

m

w

−∞

fM ,W¯ (x, y)dydx =

2m−w

e2T1 z2

√2πTdz. (2.4)

Now, we may differentiate (2.4) in order to m to get

w

−∞

fM ,W¯ (m, y)dy = 2

√2πTe(2m2T−w)2. (2.5)

Herein, we differentiate (2.5) with respect to w to obtain fM ,W¯ (m, w) = 2(2m− w)

T√

2πT e(2m−w)22T . The following two theorem below were discussed on Shreve [13].

Theorem 2.2.1. Let ¯M (T ) be the maximum of Brownian motion W (t). The joint density of ( ¯M (T ), W (T )) under measure Q, for T > 0 is

fM ,W¯ (m, w) = 2(2m− w) T√

2πT e(2m2T−w)2, on D ={(m, w) : w ≤ m, m ≥ 0}

and zero on complement of D.

Theorem 2.2.2. Let W (t) be a Brownian motion with drift α and let ¯M (T ) be the maximum of W (t). The joint density of ( ¯M (T ), W (T )) under measure ¯Q, for T > 0 is

fM ,W¯ (m, w) = 2(2m− w) T√

2πT eαw12α2T(2m2T−w)2, on D ={(m, w) : w ≤ m, m ≥ 0}

and zero on complement of D.

(23)

2.3 Joint density of Brownian motion and its minimum

Consider W (t) as a Brownian motion and denote by M (T ) = min0≤t≤TW (t) the minimum of Brownian motion W (t). We also denote by τm the first passage time at level m < 0, in this case, M (T ) ≤ m if and only if the first passage time is less or equal to time T. Therefore, in order to find the joint density of (M (T ), W (T )) we are going to apply the reflection principle, thus

P (M (t) ≤ m ∧ W (t) ≥ w) = P (W (t) ≤ 2m − w), w ≥ m, m < 0. (2.6) According to the reflection principle (2.6) and supposing that fM ,W(m, w) is the joint density of (M (T ), W (T )) for T > 0 we have

m

−∞

w

fM ,W(x, y)dxdy =

2m−w

−∞

1

2πTe2T1 z2dz. (2.7) Differentiating (2.7) with respect to m yields

w

fM ,W(m, y)dy = 1

√2πTe(2m2T−w)2. (2.8)

Now, differentiating (2.8) with respect to w yields

−fM ,W(m, w) = 2(2m− w) T√

2πT e(2m−w)22T .

Theorem 2.3.1. Let M (T ) be the minimum of Brownian motion W (T ). The joint density of (M (T ), W (T )) under measure Q, for T > 0 is given by the formula

fM ,W(m, w) = 2(w− 2m) T√

2πT e(2m2T−w)2, on D ={(m, w) : w ≥ m, m ≤ 0}

and zero on complement of D.

Theorem 2.3.2. Let W (T ) be a Brownian motion with drift α and let M (T ) be the minimum of W (T ). The joint density of (M (t), W (t)) under measure ¯Q, for T > 0 is

fM ,W(m, w) = 2(w− 2m) T√

2πT eαw−12α2T(2m−w)22T , on D ={(m, w) : w ≥ m, m ≤ 0}

and zero on complement of D.

(24)

Chapter 3

Types of Foreign Exchange Options

There exist many types of Foreign exchange options, Shamah [12] and Wystup [16] subdivide For- eign exchange options in two types, the First generation exotic options and the Second generation exotic options.

In the First generation exotic options we can find at least options such as Barrier options, Digital options, Touch options, Rebates options, Asian options, Lookback options, Forward Start options, Ratchet options, Cliquet options, Power options and Quanto options.

In the Second generation exotic options we can find at least options such as Corridors options, Faders options, Exotic Barrier options, Step up and Step down options, Forward on the harmonic average options, Variance options and Volatility swaps.

Of the above options we have just mentioned we will have a deep look into options, the Knock out options which belong to the class of Barrier options and Power options which is First generation exotic option.

The payoff’s sum of a Down and Out option(call/put) and Down and In option (call/put) is always equal to the payoff of regular vanilla option (call/put) whereas the payoff’s sum of an Up and Out option(call/put) and Up and In option(call/put) is also equal to the payoff of regular vanilla option(call/put). Therefore, it is obvious that Barrier options are cheaper than Vanilla options and that is why most dealers traded these kind of options in many cases.

3.1 Power Options

Power options are those whose payoff function is entirely or by parts raised to the power of order n. There are two types of Power Options, the Asymmetric Power Options and Symmetric Power Options [16]. The difference between these options, Asymmetric and Symmetric reside in the way as are their payoffs computed for the payoff of Asymmetric, this is entirely raised to the power of n while the payoff of Symmetric each parcel is raised to the power of n.

At maturity time T, Wystup [16] suggests, for Symmetric power call options and Symmetric

(25)

power put options, the following payoff functions

V (T ) = (max(XT − K, 0))n, (3.1)

V (T ) = (max(K − XT, 0))n, (3.2) respectively. Here, XT is the underlying at maturity time T and K the strike price.

The payoff functions for Asymmetric power call options and Asymmetric power put options are given by

V (T ) = max(XTn− Kn, 0), (3.3) V (T ) = max(Kn− XTn, 0), (3.4) respectively.

All kind of Power options in foreign exchange options satisfy the same Black-Scholes partial differential equation

.

∂F

∂t + (rd− rf)x∂F∂x + 12σX2x2 ∂∂x2F2 − rdF = 0, F (T, x) = Φ(x).

Wystup [16], in his work, only computes the discounted payoff for an Asymmetric power call option. In this project we will present discounted payoff for all Power options.

3.1.1 Discounted Payoff for Power Options

We assume that the dynamics model of the underlying foreign exchange rate is a geometric Brow- nian motion

dX(t) = X(t)(rd− rf)dt + X(t)σXdW (t)

under risk neutral measure Q. The spot of the underlying at maturity time T is given by XT = X0e(rd−rf12σ2X)T +σX

T Z.

• Risk neutral valuation for Asymmetric power call options CAP O = e−rdTEQ0,x[max(XTn− Kn, 0)] = e−rdTEQ0,x

[(XTn− Kn)1{XT>K}]

= e−rdTEQ0,x

[XTn1{XT>K}]

− e−rdTKnEQ0,x

[1{XT>K}]

= e−rdT

−∞

XTn1{XT>K}e12z2

√2πdz− e−rdTKn

−∞

1{XT>K}e12z2

√2πdz

= e−rdTX0n

−z0

en(rd−rf12σX2)T +nσX

T z· e12z2

√2πdz− e−rdTKn

−z0

e12z2

√2πdz

(26)

= e−rdTX0nen(rd−rf+n−12 σ2X)T

−z0

·e12(z−nσXT )2

√2π dz− e−rdTKnN (z0)

= e−rdTX0nen(rd−rf+n−12 σ2X)TN(

z0+ nσX T)

− e−rdTKnN (z0) where

z0 = lnXK0 +(

rd− rf 12σX2 ) T σX

T and N (x) =

x

−∞

e12z2

√2πdz.

Proposition 3.1.1. The price of an Asymmetric power call option, with exercise price K and maturity time T is given by the formula

CAP O(t, x, T, B) = e−rd(T−t)X0nen(rd−rf+n−12 σ2X)(T−t)N(

z0+ nσX

√T − t)

− e−rd(T−t)KnN (z0) (3.5) where N is the cumulative distribution function for the N [0, 1] and

z0 = lnXK0 +(

rd− rf 12σ2X)

(T − t) σX

T − t .

This result from Proposition 3.1.1 can also be found on Wystup[16] and Tompkins[15].

• Risk neutral valuation for Asymmetric power put options PAP O = e−rdTEQ0,x[max(Kn− XTn, 0)] = e−rdTEQ0,x

[(Kn− XTn)1{XT<K}]

= e−rdTKnEQ0,x

[1{XT<K}]

− e−rdTEQ0,x

[XTn1{XT<K}]

= e−rdTKn

−∞

1{XT<K}e12z2

√2πdz− e−rdT

−∞

XTn1{XT<K}e12z2

√2πdz

= e−rdTKn

z0

−∞

e12z2

√2πdz− e−rdTX0n

z0

−∞

en(rd−rf12σX2)T +nσX

T z· e12z2

√2πdz

= e−rdTKnN (z0)− e−rdTX0nen(rd−rf+n−12 σX2)T

z0

−∞

·e12(z−nσXT )2

√2π dz

= e−rdTKnN (z0)− e−rdTX0nen(rd−rf+n−12 σX2)TN(

z0− nσX

√T)

in this case

z0 =lnXK0 +(

rd− rf 12σ2X) T σX

T .

(27)

Proposition 3.1.2. The price of an Asymmetric power put option, with exercise price K and maturity time T is given by the formula

PAP O(t, x, T, K) = e−rd(T−t)KnN (z0)−e−rd(T−t)X0nen(rd−rf+n−12 σX2)(T−t)N(

z0−nσX

(T − t)) , (3.6) where N is the cumulative distribution function for the N [0, 1] and

z0 =lnXK0 +(

rd− rf 12σ2X)

(T − t) σX

T − t .

Remark : This result from Proposition 3.1.2 is not in the literature as far as we know.

Proposition 3.1.3. Consider an Asymmetric European power call and an Asymmetric Eu- ropean power put both with strike price K and exercise time T. Denoting the corresponding pricing functions by CAP O(t, x, T, K) and PAP O(t, x, T, K) we have the following relation,

CAP O(t, x, T, K)− PAP O(t, x, T, K) = e−rd(T−t)xnen(rd−rf+n−12 σX2)(T−t) − e−rd(T−t)Kn. (3.7)

• Risk neutral valuation for Symmetric power call options CSP O = e−rdTEQ0,x[(max(XT − K, 0))n] = e−rdTEQ0,x

[((XT − K)1{XT>K})n]

= e−rdTEQ0,x

[ n

j=0

(n j

)

(−K)jXTn−j1{XT>K}

]

= e−rdT

n j=0

(n j

)

(−K)jE[

XTn−j1{XT>K}]

= e−rdT

n j=0

(n j

) (−K)j

−∞

XTn−j1{XT>K}e12z2

√2π dz

= e−rdT

n j=0

(n j

)

(−K)jX0n−j

−z0

e(n−j)(rd−rf12σX2)T +(n−j)σX

T z· e12z2

√2πdz

= e−rdT

n j=0

(n j

)

(−K)jX0n−je(n−j)(rd−rf+n−j−12 σ2X)T

−z0

·e12(z−(n−j)σXT )2

√2π dz

= e−rdT

n j=0

(n j

)

(−K)jX0n−je(n−j)(rd−rf+n−j−12 σ2X)TN(

z0+ (n− j)σX

√T)

where

z0 = lnXK0 +(

rd− rf 12σ2X) T σX

√T .

References

Related documents

I detta fanns ett intresse att med hjälp av olika bilder undersöka om smink och ålder hade någon inverkan på hur man bedömer en annan kvinna utifrån endast

If Sweden has a flexible exchange rate regime and a shock hits Sweden, then the nominal exchange rate immediately appreciates just enough to keep the Swedish goods market in long

Specifically, cumulative crop consumptive use and total dry biomass production were extracted for selected water districts within the southern San Joaquin Valley for a base

Based on previous studies by Forbes, Hjortsoe and Nenova (2018) and Ha, Stocker and Yilmazkunday (2019) who emphasizes the importance of interpreting the underlying shock causing

Secondly, we will test whether capital control level and exchange rate regime have impact on the relationship between foreign exchange rate movement and stock return

We can deduce from this is that it can become more difficult to achieve profits through carrying trades when entering random trades for longer maturities even if the

M&amp;As can be categorized according to the relationship between the combining companies into four different types: vertical (a combination of two organizations from

The input variables when applying the model to a foreign exchange market is the different time series values, input 1 is today’s value, input 2 is yesterdays value and so on..