• No results found

Market structure and market power : the case of the Swedish forest sector

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Market structure and market power : the case of the Swedish forest sector"

Copied!
38
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

MARKET STRUCTURE AND

MARKET POWER

The Case of the Swedish Forest Sector

by

Mats À. Bergman

Umeå Economic Studies No. 296

UNIVERSITY OF UMEÅ 1993

(2)
(3)

MARKET STRUCTURE AND

MARKET POWER

The Case of the Swedish Forest Sector

A K A D E M ISK A VHANDLING

Som, med vederbörligt tillstånd av rektorsämbetet vid

Umeå universitet fö r vinnande av filosofie doktorsexamen

framlägges till offentlig granskning vid

institutionen fö r nationalekonomi

HÖRSAL C, SamhäUsvetarhuset, Umeå universitet

Fredagen den 26 februari 1993, kl 10.15

av

Mats A. Bergman

Fil. kand.

(4)

Author and title

Bergman Mats A. (1993)

Market Structure and Market Power: The Case of the Swedish Forest Sector. Umeå Economic Studies No. 296,140 pages.

Abstract

The Swedish forest sector is analyzed, using methods drawing on traditional (forest) market analysis and industrial organization literature. Models based on economic theory are tested empirically with time-6eries data.

Paper [1] deals with how the pulp and paper industry manages wood supply risk. It appears as if the import of wood is not counter-cyclical to the domestic supplies of wood. Instead, the inventory is used to absorb unexpected shifts in supply.

In paper [2], the supply behaviour is compared between different categories of forest owners. The supply elasticities with respect to prices are found to be much smaller in this study, which is based on quantities of thinning wood and final felling wood, than in other studies using pulpwood and sawtimber quantities. Only small differences are found between owner categories.

Paper [3] attempts to estimate parametrically the market power (the ‘markdown’) of the assumedlv monopsonistic pulp and paper industry, using a restricted Gene­ ralized Leontief (GL) profit function to model the production structure. The hypothesis of a competitive market can be rejected, when the alternative hypothe­ sis is a variable degree of market power.

Paper [4] clarifies some notions raised by the use of the restricted GL profit func­ tion. A specification of the profit fuction is proposed, where linear homogeneity in the fixed factor is nested in the non-homogeneous case.

The final paper [5] explores the weakening of a natural resource monopsony’s market power, if time-consistency (or subgame-perfection) is required in a two- period model. The analysis resembles that of a monopoly selling a durable good (Coase conjecture). The monopsony does loose market power, but its position is strengthened if the resource is renewable or if it grows between periods.

Keywords: Swedish forest industry, market form, industrial organization, oligopso­ ny, monopsony, time consistency, natural resources, supply risk, restricted Genera­ lized Leontief, profit function, roundwood, pulpwood, Coase conjecture.

Distribution and author’s address: Department of Economics, University of Umeå, S-401 87 Umeå, Sweden.

(5)

MARKET STRUCTURE AND

MARKET POWER

The Case of the Swedish Forest Sector

by

Mats A. Bergman

Umeå Economic Studies No. 296

UNIVERSITY OF UMEÅ 1993

(6)

Copyright Mats A. Bergman Department of Economics University of Umeå 1993 ISSN: 0348-1018 ISBN: 91-7174-755-9

(7)

Abstract

The Swedish forest sector is analyzed, using methods drawing on traditional (forest) market analysis and industrial organization literature. Models based on economic theory are tested empirically with time-series data.

Paper [1] deals with how the pulp and paper industry manages wood supply risk. It appears as if the import of wood is not counter-cyclical to the domestic supplies of wood. Instead, the inventory is used to absorb unexpected shifts in supply.

In paper [2], the supply behaviour is compared between different categories of forest owners. The supply elasticities with respect to prices are found to be much smaller in this study, which is based on quantities of thinning wood and final felling wood, than in other studies using pulpwood and sawtimber quantities. Only sitiall differences are found between owner categories.

Paper [3] attempts to estimate parametrically the market power (the ‘markdown’) oft the assumedly monopsonistic pulp and paper industry, using a restricted Gene­ ralized Leontief (GL) profit function to model the production structure. The hypothesis of a competitive market can be rejected, when the alternative hypothe­ sis is a variable degree of market power.

Paper [4] clarifies some notions raised by the use of the restricted GL profit func­ tion. A specification of the profit fuction is proposed, where linear homogeneity in the fixed factor is nested in the non-homogeneous case.

The final paper [5] explores the weakening of a natural resource monopsony’s market power, if time-consistency (or subgame-perfection) is required in a two- period model. The analysis resembles that of a monopoly selling a durable good (Coase conjecture). The monopsony does loose market power, but its position is strengthened if the resource is renewable or if it grows between periods.

Keywords: Swedish forest industry, market form, industrial organization, oligopso­ ny, monopsony, time consistency, natural resources, supply risk, restricted Genera­ lised Leontief, profit function, roundwood, pulpwood, Coase conjecture.

(8)
(9)

Acknowledgements

Random events often seem to govern our choices. In the Fall of 1987, I was asked to work in the project ‘The Swedish Roundwood Market*, led by my advisor K arl-G ustaf Löfgren. At that time, I had not finished my B. Sc., and Karl-Gustaf was visiting Berkeley, so it was a slow start.

A single phrase of the instructions I was first given, stuck in my mind: I was asked to ”extend and improve” Runar Brännlund’s analysis of the Swedish roundwood market. That analysis constituted Runar*s thesis, which was due to be published in less than a year. The task seemed almost insurmountable at that time, although I now realize that the intention was not that I should write a better thesis than Runar. The idea must have been to indicate where I should direct my efforts, while underlining the obvious: that I must do something at least slightly different from what had previously been done. I think that those few words have, to some extent, determined the path of my work on this thesis. Maybe as a consequence of my aiming for a ‘deepened and extended* analysis, the thesis is a rather eclectic collec­ tion of papers, rather than a comprehensive analysis of (some aspect of) the round­ wood market, as most of the theses in this field are.

To the extent I have managed to see further than my predecessors, it is only because I have stood on their shoulders. The most solid and invaluable support in my work has been given by Karl-Gustaf. He has guided me around many of the pitfalls of science, always encouraging. Karl-Gustaf, Thomas Aronsson, Runar Brännlund and Lars Hultkrantz have, with their research, provided me with a paradigm from which to learn. The many discussions I have had with them over the past five years, their numerous suggestions for improvements to my own work and the fruitful cooperation with Karl-Gustaf and Runar in three of the papers have made this thesis much better. Also, I wish to thank Kurt Brännas, Tönu Puu, Lars Westin and Magnus Wikström among others at the Department of Economics, University of Umeå, my colleges at the Department of Forest Econo­ mics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Jörgen W. Weibull at the

(10)

A ckn ow ledgem ents

Department of Economics, University of Stockholm and participants in the semi­ nars I have given over the years. Their suggestions and advice have greatly im­ proved the quality of my thesis. Chris Hudson at the Department of Political Science, University of Umeå, has meant a lot for my English. The esthetic qualities of the layout of this thesis are due to Ing-Marie Nilsson.

Financial support from the Non-Industrial Private Forest Owner’s Fund for Forest Research and from the Swedish Council for Forestry and Agricultural Research are gratefully acknowledged. Finally, the strong support of my wife and my family was, of course, a necessary condition for this thesis ever to be written.

Umeå, January 1993

(11)

The thesis consists of this summary and the following papers:

[1] Bergman, M.A. and Löfgren, K.G. (1991), Supply Risk Management Under Imperfect Competition — Empirical Applications to the Swedish Pulp and Paper Industry, Empirical Economics 16, 447-464.

[2] Bergman, M.A. (1992), Differences in Final Felling and Thinning Beha­ viour Between Owner Categories in Sweden, Scandinavian Journal o f

Forest Research 7, 269—283.

[3] Bergman, M.A. and Brännlund, R. (1992), Measuring Oligopsony Power. An Application to the Swedish Pulp and Paper Industry, Umeå Econo­ mic Studies No. 285, University of Umeå.

[4] Bergman, M.A. and Brännlund, R. (1992), A Note on the Application of the Restricted Generalized Leontief Profit Function, revised version forthcoming in Economics Letters.

[5] Bergman, M.A. (1992), Natural Resource Monopsony in a Two-Period Model, Umeå Economic Studies No. 266, University of Umeå. Revised version.

I am indebted to Physica-Verlag and Scandinavian University Press for permission to include Paper [1] and Paper [2] respectively in the thesis.

(12)
(13)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 1

The Swedish Forest Sector

The importance of the forest sector can be underlined by the fact that forestry and the forest industry directly employ close to four percent of the Swedish labour force. The export of forest products accounts for almost a fifth of the total value of the Swedish export. The purpose of the present thesis is to study some specific aspects of the wood market, concerning the supply behaviour of the forest owners, the purchasing policy of the buyers and the balance of market power between the buyers and sellers.

The sawmills and the pulp and paper industry are quite evenly distributed over the country, with the exception that the pulp and paper industry in the northern half of Sweden is concentrated on the east coast. Three fifths of the land area is covered with forests. The forest inventories by cubic meters in the four regions Götaland, Svealand and Southern and Northern Norrland are of approximately the same size. Spruce and pine account for 85 percent of the inventory. A little less than half of the forest land and a little more than half of the forest inventory are owned by a quarter of a million private forest owners. (A greater proportion of the forest land is privately owned in the southern part of Sweden, where soil fertility is higher.) The public sector and the forest industry, in particular the pulp and paper industry, own approximately a quarter of the forest land each.

In the first half of the 20th century, fellings averaged around 50 million cubic meters (standing volume) per year. The volumes increased in the 1950s and 1960s, to a peak of 70 million cubic meters in the first half of the 1970s. Since the re­ cession of 1976-77, fellings have averaged around 60 million cubic meters, with a slight tendency to increase. The value of the fellings measured at the roadside was, in the cutting year 1989/90, almost 19 billion SEK. In the last decades, the annual increments have outgrown fellings by up to 30 million cubic meters per year, resulting in a forest inventory that is 35 percent larger than 40 years ago. In the 1970s there were worries that the forests would be depleted; in the early 1980s the debate was dominated by the (buyers’) opinion that the private forest owners’ unwillingness to fell caused an unwarranted wood shortage and excessive prices; today the problem seems to be to find an outlet for all the wood available.

Most wood is either used by the pulp and paper industry (pulpwood) or by the sawmill industry (sawtimber). The two industries use roughly the same amount of ‘fresh’ wood. In addition, the pulp and paper industry buys waste products from

(14)

2 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

the sawmill industry, amounting to 40 percent of the wood input of the latter. A third of the trees (by volume) can be used either as pulpwood or sawtimber, which allows for competition between the two industries. However, it appears as if the pulp and paper industry has a much stronger position. Its value added is almost four times that of the sawmill industry. It owns a quarter of the forest land, where­ as the sawmill companies own almost no land. The seven largest firms use more than 90 percent, and the three largest more than three fifths of the pulpwood. The third largest firm is partly owned by the second largest. The sawmill industry is much less concentrated, with almost 2500 sawmills scattered throughout Sweden. Nevertheless, 10 percent of the sawmills account for 90 percent of the production.

The market power of the pulp and paper industry is further strengthened by the fact that five of the largest firms, including the three largest, only buy pulpwood through commonly owned regional purchasing companies (in northern Sweden, a purchasing cartel). This cartelisation of pulpwood purchases is not considered illegal, on the grounds that it cannot be shown that the consumers of the final products are hurt by higher prices!1 The sawmill industry does have organizations that coordinate price and purchasing policies, although these are apparently less successful in reducing internal competition.

In order to strengthen their position v is -a -v is the buyers, the forest owners organized in forest owners associations. By the mid-1970s, more than half of the forest owners had become members. In the aftermath of some quite unsuccessful attempts to integrate forward, i.e., to acquire a cooperatively owned pulp and paper industry, many of the members left the Forest Owners Association. Today, a third of the private forest owners are organized. Considering that two thirds of the private forest owners receive less than 10 percent of their income from forestry, it is understandable if their loyalty to their organization is limited.

Wood can be bought in two distinct markets, or according to two types of con­ tracts. The first is the market for delivered wood. The price in this market is governed by annual agreements, which are typically settled in the autumn, after negotiations between the buyers’ and the sellers’ organizations. If no agreement can be reached — as is quite often the case — either one or other of the price propo­ sals will become dominant, depending on the market situation. The price is paid according to volume and quality, and includes the felling cost and the cost of 1 However, the relevant Act has been revised. When the new Act comes into

(15)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 3

transporting the logs to a road. In the second market, the market for standing timber, the price does not include felling and transportation to a road — these costs must be met by the buyer. In contrast to the market for delivered wood, the price must be settled in every individual transaction and the price is negotiated per stand, not per cubic meter. Unfortunately, reliable data is available neither for prices nor for quantities in this market. It is claimed that prices are often higher in the market for standing timber. The market for standing timber is the smaller of the two — accounting for approximately one third of the total.

The price lists used in the market for delivered wood should be regarded as a price offer by the seller, valid for one year. The market for standing timber adds flexibi­ lity, as prices can be adjusted anytime.

More details on the institutional arrangements of the Swedish roundwood market and the forest industry can be found in, e.g., Wiberg (1987), Bergman (1988), Bergfors, Bergman and Hultkrantz (1988), Brännlund (1988), Aronsson (1990), Carlén (1990) and in the Statistical Yearbook of Forestry.

Introduction

The forest sector is important to Sweden. Therefore, it deserves to be studied, in its own right. However, this is not the sole aim of this thesis. Another ambition is to demonstrate, and to some extent develop, methods that can be used to study markets in general.

The approach of this thesis is eclectic, rather than comprehensive. The aim is not a unified, multi-purpose model of the forest sector, but a deepened understanding of some specific issues. Therefore, the papers build on earlier work by other authors, extending their analyses in some directions. As the wood market has been the subject of a number of studies, this appears to be an appropriate method.

The organization of forestry and the pulp and paper industry in Sweden is ana­ lyzed from basically four aspects. The first is: how does the monopsonistic2 pulp and paper industry manage the risk associated with a stochastic supply of pulp- wood? Secondly, do the different types of forest owners differ in their behaviour, 2 A monopsony is a single buyer of a certain good (in a certain market), just as

(16)

4 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

i.e., in their responses to changing prices, forest inventory et cetera? This could perhaps be expected if the pulp and paper industry used its own forests to counteract the stochastic fluctuations in the supply from the other forest owners. Both of these questions are analyzed given an assumption used in many earlier studies of the forest sector: that the pulp and paper industry is monopsonistic.

Although firmly based on observations of the actual wood market, it became increasingly unsatisfying to assume that the market was monopsonistic, without actually testing the hypothesis of competitive behaviour. This is the third aspect analyzed. The outcome of the analysis gave rise to yet another question: given the institutional set up of the pulpwood market, which strongly suggests a monopso­ nistic market, why is the empirical evidence of the buyer's market power so weak? The final paper develops ideas originating from Coase (1973), suggesting that in a multi-period market exchange, a durable-good monopoly may in fact be unable to exploit its market power. If the consumers are rational, they will foresee that the price will be lowered in the future. In effect, the monopoly competes with itself. In the pulpwood monopsony problem, the situation is similar: if the pulpwood buyers offer too low a price, the forest owners may well postpone fellings, anticipating a higher future price.

Analyzing the Organization of an Industry

The first two papers, [1] and [2], are empirical market analyses of a few aspects of the Swedish pulpwood market. The methodology is a straightforward application of traditional economics, but the models used are developed to address the specific questions at hand. The papers are written in the same spirit as a large part of the modern empirically oriented literature on forest economics, e.g., Binkley (1979), Dasgupta and Heal (1979), Brännlund, Johansson and Löfgren (1985), Johansson and Löfgren (1985), Brännlund (1988), Kuuluvainen (1989), and Aronsson (1990).

The short note [3] and the two concluding papers [4] and [5] have been influenced by the industrial organization literature, as well as the above mentioned sources of inspiration. The empirical study of industries with market power dates back to Bain (1951). Following his pioneering work, the prevalent ‘structure-conduct- performance paradigm' focused on cross-section studies of firms and industries. The profit, as reported in the accounting data, was modelled as a function of such structural measures as industry concentration indices.

(17)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 5

More recently, a new line of research has developed, that recognizes the difficulties of observing marginal costs and of comparing profitability between industries or firms. Instead, the production structure of a single industry is estimated from aggregated time-series data on prices and quantities. This method makes it possi­ ble to test the hypothesis of competitive behaviour directly. A survey of this literature has been made by Bresnahan (1989). Appelbaum (1979 and 1982) and Atkinson and Kerkvliet (1990) are good examples of empirical applications, as well as theoretical developments.

The final Paper [5] is inspired by the more purely theoretical industrial organiza­ tion literature, as it can be found in, e.g., Tirole (1988). This literature relies, to a large extent, on game theoretical methods. The problem must often be formulated simply — sometimes over-simply — for a solution to be possible, because of the complex analysis required in game theory. This is reflected in the models used in industrial organization — they are often so simplified that they cannot seriously be thought of as representing reality. Instead, their purpose is to illustrate and exem­ plify specific aspects of real life, that have yet to be incorporated in more general models of, e.g., a market such as the pulpwood market. The aspect brought into the analysis by the final paper is the complication of time-consistency.

Method

In Papers [1] to [3], formal models based on economic theory are developed, which are then subjected to empirical testing. The aim of each paper is to answer a question, concerning a specific aspect of the roundwood market. Ideally, the prob­ lem is formulated so that the question at hand corresponds to an hypothesis, which can be tested with the model and the empirical data. The hypothesis may be rejected, meaning that we can eliminate a specific answer to the question we posed. For example, in the fairly clear cut case of Paper [3], we wish to evaluate how much market power the pulp and paper industry has in the market for pulp- wood. The hypothesis we try to reject is that the market is competitive. In reduc­ ing the problem to the testing of such a hypotheses, the degree of abstraction becomes high. Many aspects of the real world are disregarded in order for the model to be manageable, and much of the relevant (qualitative) data must be left unused, as it can not be fitted into the model. The data we did not use in this particular case ranges from anecdotal reports of collusive behaviour to annual industry profits and rates of return to total capital, as found in the Official Statis­

(18)

6 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

tics of Sweden. This amounts to a huge loss of information, which, however, must be traded off against the virtue of a sound basis in economic theory and an objec­ tive statistical test (as long as the assumptions incorporated in the model are true). In many circumstances, it might be wiser to use all the data available, in a more pragmatic approach, especially if the single desideratum is an answer to the question posed. On the other hand, one option does not preclude the other. Using the more formal approach, we know something of the extent to which we can trust the answer: at which confidence level we can reject the hypothesis, given our assumptions. The rigor imposed by the formal models forces one to be very exact about assumptions and conclusions, and may therefore lead to a better understand­ ing of the problem. Bartholomew (1982) argues, in favour of simple mathematical models, that

"Social phenomena are often exceedingly complex and our models are bound to be simplifications. Even if it is allowed that our model need only repro­ duce the relevant features of the real process the problem remains formi­ dable. However, we would argue that there is no alternative to simlification. The basic limiting factor is not the mathematical apparatus available but the ability of the human mind to grasp a complex situation. There is no point in building models whose ramifications are beyond our comprehension. Perhaps the only safeguard against oversimplification is to use a battery of models instead of a single one."3

There is also a value in the theoretical exercise: many of the advances in economic theory are the results of problems encountered in empirical research.4 This brings us to another line of demarcation: that towards more theoretically oriented econo­ mics. Only the final paper can be said to belong to this tradition. A purely theore­ tical analysis can give valuable insights into very practical problems, but just as in the pragmatic, descriptive approach, we do not test our hypotheses against empiri­ cal data.

Malinvaud (1981), on the contrary, considers the predominance of simple and schematic representations of complex issues in the (macro) economics litera­ ture the cause of many unfounded conclusions. This argument is not taken to imply that mathematical modelling should be abandoned. Rather, according to Malinvaud, the models should be made more realistic (and thus more complex), while being subjected to scrutinous empirical testing. However, as a first and often enlightening approximation, Malinvaud considers the simple models quite acceptable.

(19)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w er 7

In contrast, the textbook piece of science includes theory formulation, the deriva­ tion of testable hypotheses and testing against data. The hypothesis — and thus the theory — can be rejected by the data, but not confirmed. Only through a series of failed attempts to reject the theory, either directly or through its implications, can we become more confident that our theory reflects some aspect of the real world. Nevertheless — even if we do not subject our theory to empirical testing — we may still gain in understanding from it.

The level of aggregation should also be mentioned. The data is aggregated to industry level. The theory starts from the behaviour of a single firm or forest owner, but the aggregation is raised to industry level by the assumption of a representative forest owner or firm, or by the assumption of monopsony. The level of analysis is motivated partly by the set of questions posed and partly by the availability of data. The use of industry-wide price and quantity data, rather than firm accounting data, can also be justified by a scepticism regarding the latter’s ability to measure true costs.

A time-series study has both advantages and disadvantages, compared with a cross-section study. If we are more interested in how behaviour varies between different agents at a given moment in time, a cross-section study should be chosen. If our concern is with the development of behaviour over time, and with dynamics, time-series data is more appropriate.5 The choice of this thesis, the time-series approach, is not based on the belief that this method is superior. It merely reflects the necessity to choose one of two paths.

Finally, the models are set in a partial equilibrium framework, rather than in general equilibrium. This appears to be the most natural, when studying a single industry. The level of abstraction and aggregation necessary for the models to be general equilibrium would presumably cost more in terms of simplifications, than the gain in completeness would be worth.

If we want all of these qualities, panel data is a good choice, although data gathering may be costly in terms of time and effort.

(20)

8 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

Summary of the papers6

Paper [1] Supply Risk Management Under Imperfect Competition — Empiri­ cal Applications to the Swedish Pulp and Paper Industry

The decision problem of a firm facing an uncertain demand has been studied by Baron (1971), Leland (1972) and Weitzman (1974). The firm can either choose a price, and sell an uncertain quantity, or it can choose to produce a certain quanti­ ty, to be sold at an uncertain price. Lim (1980 and 1981), Sengupta (1986) and Löfgren and Ranneby (1987) analyse under which conditions one of the strategies is preferable to the other; the last of the three deals with the problem of uncertain supply.

The Swedish pulp and paper industry is subject to uncertainty concerning its pulpwood supply. It buys approximately three quarters of its pulpwood from domestic sources (including residues/waste products from the sawmill industry); the remaining part is either imported or supplied from the industry’s own forests. The special characteristics of the domestic market aggravate the supply risk: as the price in the largest part of the domestic market (the market for delivered wood) is annually set in advance, there is no guarantee that the supplied volume equals the demanded volume. Presumably, the pulp and paper industry takes action to prevent the wood inventory from running out completely or piling up indefinitely.

This could be done in either of two ways (or a combination of both). First, the representative firm could use one or more of the other markets, i.e., the market for standing timber, the import market or its own forests (where price does not need to be set in advance) as ‘backstop markets’. Second, the firm could let the (posi­ tive or negative) unexpected component of the supply be absorbed by the invento­ ry, and only the next year try to restore the inventory to its optimal level by adjusting the price in the market for delivered wood.

In order to shed some light on how the pulp and paper industry actually manages this supply risk, a monopsony model is formulated, in which the firm first sets the domestic price and receives a quantity determined by the price and a random

No alterations have been made in the two published papers, [1] and [2]. Instead, an errata and some more extensive comments are found in the Appendix of this summary.

(21)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 9

element. In the next stage, the firm chooses a quantity in the international market, the price of which is determined by the supply curve and a random element7. Furthermore, the firm is assumed to aim for an optimal inventory level. The deviation from the optimal level enters the firm’s wood demand function additive- ly, so that the estimated coefficient (between 50 and 80 percent in our model) is the share of the inventory surplus/deficit that it wants to eliminate in one year.

The empirical results show that the pulp and paper industry does not, in fact, appear to use imports as a backstop for the domestic market. Presumably, imports are made throughout the whole year. Instead, it seems as if the inventory is used to absorb the fluctuations in wood supply; the error term in our wood supply model and the change in inventory follow each other closely. Unfortunately, there is no data on the inventory of bought, but not yet cut, standing timber — this inventory is reported to be of approximately the same size as the inventory of cut pulp wood. Had such data been available, the model fit would possibly have been even better.

Paper [2] Differences in Final Felling and Thinning Behaviour Between Owner Categories in Sweden

Timber and/or pulpwood supply, i.e., the question of how forest owners felling decisions respond to prices and other economic variables, has been studied in a number of scientific works, such as Binkley (1979), Brännlund (1988), Kuuluvainen (1989), Hultkrantz and Aronsson (1989), Aronsson (1990), Carlén (1990) and Hetemäki and Kuuluvainen (1990). The cited authors have used either timenseries or cross-section data in two-period models. Typically, the supply prob­ lem is modelled as either a choice of total wood supply, or as a choice between supplying pulpwood and sawtimber. Furthermore, they focus on either private or aggregate wood supply.

A number of studies have addressed the problem of how thinnings are used to increase future growth more theoretically, using multiperiod or continuous time models, e.g., Näslund (1969), Kilkki and Väisänen (1970), Wernerheim (1989) and

Ideally, we would like to estimate a model, in which the firm also uses the market for standing timber as a backstop market. However, it is not possible to obtain data on quantities in this market.

(22)

10 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

Clark (1990). Lohmander (1987), Clarke and Reed (1988) and Reed and Clarke (1990) study the supply decision under price uncertainty.

Paper [2] explicitly considers thinnings and final fellings — the actions the forest owner actually takes — while still retaining the simple structure of the two-period models of wood supply. The behaviour of the forest owners is allowed to differ between private persons, the public sector and companies. To simplify the analy­ sis, the endowment of the representative forest owner is split into two unrelated classes of wood: thinning wood and final felling wood. This means that the effect of thinnings on future final felling is disregarded.

The model is confronted with Swedish time series data. In particular, the data on felling quantities are based on the Swedish National Forest Survey’s stump enume­ ration, as are the, in this context previously unused, data on forest inventories by owner category and m aturity class. From the data, it can be seen that thinnings have decreased and final fellings have increased during the period of study (1955 to 1987). It is also notable that while the private forest owners have increased the level of thinning relative to their stock of thinning wood, the companies have reduced theirs. Each year, approximately two percent of the volume in the thinn­ ing woods is harvested. All owner categories have reduced their final fellings rela­ tive to their stock of final felling wood by approximately one percentage point over the period of study. The companies now cut three percent of their final felling stock each year, while the private and the public owners only cut around two percent.

The forest owner chooses between final felling and thinning, but the result of the action taken, if any, is a mixture of pulpwood and final felling. Therefore, a simple transformation function is formulated, where it is assumed that pulpwood and sawtimber make up fixed shares of the final felling wood, and of the thinning wood. It can be conjectured that the shares should be dependent on the relative prices of pulpwood and sawtimber. However, the assumption of fixed shares appears to be supported by the data.

A surprising result of the model estimation is that the price appears to have a very small effect on wood supply, if any. This contradicts the results of all the empiri­ cally oriented work cited above, where the own price elasticity ranges from 0.4 to

(23)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 11

over 2.8 On the other hand, the supply elasticity with respect to inventory is found to be, on average, a little less than unity, which is higher than most of the corresponding estimates reported in the literature. A partial reconciliation can be made between the results of this paper and those of, e.g., Brännlund (1988): the elasticities reported by Brännlund include fairly high negative cross price elastici­ ties between pulpwood and sawtimber. Thus, the total supply price elasticity with respect to a uniform price increase is virtually the same in both studies.

Only small differences are found between the supply behaviour of different owner types: the private forest owners appear to respond more strongly to cutting cost changes and less strongly to inventory changes than do the others.

Paper [3] Measuring Oligopsony Power. An application to the Swedish Pulp and Paper Industry

A shortcoming Papers [1] and [2] share with many other studies of the Swedish pulpwood market, is that they are based on the assumption that the market can be characterized as monopsonistic.9 There is indeed much evidence to support such an argument: for example, the number of independent firms in the pulp and paper industry has shrunk dramatically, leaving Sweden with only three major firms (Stora, SCA and MoDo). Furthermore, the users of more than 75 percent of the pulpwood, including the three major firms, buy through common purchasing companies.

The aim of Paper [3] is to develop an empirical test that addresses the question of the market form, and to apply the test to the Swedish pulpwood market. Two pioneering papers in this area are Appelbaum (1979) and (1982). Bresnahan (1989) provides a survey of the literature. Naturally, most studies concentrate on the monopsony/oligopsony problem. One exception is Atkinson and Kerkvliet (1990), who estimate both monopoly and monopsony power, using a dual representation of the production structure. As in much of the literature, they do not simultaneously estimate the demand for the output (or the supply of the input). Therefore, they

This means that when the price of wood increases with 1 per cent, the supply of wood increases with between 0.4 and 2 per cent.

Brännlund (1989), for example, estimates the welfare loss due to monopsony, conditioned on the assumption that the roundwood market is monopsonistic.

(24)

12 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

cannot separate the slopes of the demand and supply curves from the respective conjectural elasticities10 terms. This means that if they, for example, fail to find monopoly power, this could be due either to competition in the market, or to a very elastic demand curve.

A conjectural variation model is formulated, where all firms are assumed to have identical production functions. From this, it follows that the conjectural elastici­ ties are equal. We adopt the dual representation of the production structure. Thus, we start with a profit function, specified as a Generalized Leontief function, i.e., a flexible form profit function. The properties of this function are further developed in Paper [4]. It can be noted that we use a specification that allows the profit function to be either homogeneous of degree 1 or non-homogeneous in the fixed input (capital), with the homogeneous case nested in the non-homogeneous case. Using Hotelling’s lemma, the supply and demand functions can be derived from the profit function. These functions are estimated with three stage least squares and full information maximum likelihood, yielding estimates of the parameters of the profit function.

In the empirical section, we are able to test the hypothesis that the conjectural elasticity is zero, i.e., that the market is competitive, independently from the pulpwood supply elasticity. The evidence is somewhat inconclusive. The null hypothesis of competitive behaviour cannot be rejected, when tested against an hypothesis of a constant degree of oligopsony power. However, when tested against an hypothesis of a variable degree of market power, it can be rejected. This can be interpreted as support for the notion that there have been periods of fairly strong oligopsony power, as well as competitive periods. Such a pattern is compatible with a cartel, which, during some periods, manages to restrict competition, but at others is unable to prevent the firms from competing intensely.

Paper [4] A Note on the Application of the Restricted Generalized Leontief Profit Function

Diewert (1973) proposed a modification of the Leontief (profit) function: the Generalized Leontief (GL) function, with the attractive property that it is a second order approximation to an arbitrary function in a given point. This func-The elasticities of market demand/supply with respect to firm demand for the input/supply of the output.

(25)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 13

tion has been widely used in the economics literature. Diewert also proposed a profit function specification in the case where one or more of the inputs is fixed; the restricted GL profit function.

If the profit function is homogeneous of degree 1 in the fixed inputs, we must have constant returns to scale in all inputs. This restriction is assumed to hold in the specifications proposed by Diewert. However, when the restricted GL profit func­ tion is applied in studies of monopoly/oligopoly behaviour, homogeneity in the fixed factor is not obvious (see e.g., Lopez (1984) and Wear and Newman (1991)). In Paper [4], we propose a general specification, where homogeneity is a special case of the non-homogeneous restricted GL profit function. We also clarify the conditions under which a profit function is a second order approximation to an arbitrary function, while still satisfying the necessary conditions of a profit func­ tion. The drawbacks of the papers by Lopez and Wear and Newman are briefly discussed.

Paper [5] Natural Resource Monopsony in a Two-Period Model

The final paper of the thesis addresses the paradox left by the somewhat inconclu­ sive evidence of Paper [3]: if the number of firms in the Swedish pulp and paper industry is so small, and if they cooperate so closely, why is the statistical evidence of monopsonistic or oligopsonistic behaviour so weak? When our casual observa­ tions so strongly suggest collusion, we would expect a high and significant degree of market power throughout the whole period, not just intermittently. A very similar conclusion was reached in an earlier, more pragmatic paper (Bergfors, Bergman and Hultkrantz (1988)).

Coase (1973) conjectured that a monopoly selling a durable good, when facing rational consumers, would be forced to sell the good at marginal cost. The argu­ ment goes as follows: assume that consumers with a high valuation buy quickly at a high price. Once these consumers have bought, the monopoly has an incentive to lower the price and sell to consumers with a low valuation. If the monopoly cannot commit itself to sustain the high price, all consumers will predict that the price will be lowered. Therefore, no buyer will buy at the initial high price — they will wait for the price to be lowered. According to Coase’s conjecture, the only stable (time-consistent or subgame-perfect) equilibrium is one where the price equals the marginal cost all along. This conjecture has subsequently been proved for certain

(26)

14 M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

cases by Stokey (1981), Gul, Sonnenschein and Wilson (1986) and Ausubel and Deneckere (1989). However, the latter, as well as Bulow (1982) and Bagnoli, Salant and Swierzbinski (1989) showed that the results are sensitive to the assumptions. Given a slightly different set of assumptions, Coase’s conjecture does not hold.

Almost nothing can be found in the economics literature concerning the problem of a monopsonist facing many small sellers of a (before extraction) ‘durable* input, such as wood, minerals or fossil fuels. Paper [5] uses a two-period model, resem­ bling the monopoly model of Bulow, to explore whether a monopsonist can be the subject of a similar weakening of its market power. It is found that the loss of market power is of approximately the same magnitude as in the monopoly case. The basic model is extended in two ways: new forest land is allowed to enter the market in the second period, and the standing trees are allowed to grow between periods. It is found that both extensions strengthen the position of the buyer. Nevertheless, the time-consistency requirement does weaken the market power of the monopsonist. It is possible that some of the explanation of the discrepancy between expected and empirically observed market power lies in the dynamic nature of the wood market, and in the pulp and paper industry’s inability to commit.

Further research

Paper [1] could be improved by including data on the supply of wood from the pulp and paper industry’s own forests in the model. The production structure of the industry could be represented by a flexible function model, similar to the one used in Paper [3].

The conclusion reached in Paper [2] — that the price of wood has no significant effect on wood supply — must be viewed as tentative, considering that almost all earlier studies have found significantly positive price effects. Thus, more research on this question, and on the issue of negative cross price elasticities between pulp- wood and sawtimber supply, would be valuable.

In Paper [3], we test the market power of the buyers of wood, conditional on the assumption that all firms are alike. A more realistic model of the Swedish

(27)

round-M arket S tru ctu re and, round-M arket P o w e r 15

wood market would allow for some heterogeneity between firms. A possible set up is a cartel — the large firms that buy through purchasing companies — competing against a fringe of small competitive firms. Using the dual approach of Paper [3], the conjectural elasticities and the size of the cartel could perhaps be estimated.

Paper [5] could be elaborated in many ways. The two-period model could be ex­ tended to a multi-period, infinité-horizon model. Within the two-period context, capacity restrictions in the pulp production (wood consumption) could be imposed. The assumption of no capacity restrictions is of course a simplification. The indus­ try cannot buy more wood than it can use, given its production capacity. Thus, the capacity decision serves as a commitment not to buy more than a maximum amount. If the investment decision was explicitly modelled within the game, the dynamic interplay between the single buyer and the many sellers would be en­ riched and would gain in realism.

(28)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r

Appendix: Corrections and comments

Paper [1] Supply Risk Management Under Imperfect Competition — Empirical Applications to the Swedish Pulp and Paper Industry

Misprintings et cetera Page 448 Row(Eqv.) Stands 450 452 453 454 455 10 32 14 23 (8) 16 ( 12) 14 16 volume at a certain price differs interprete as assumed support [c,d] d “ Cl/ r i( e domestric + «1(7) where we would

(Table 1) Total dis­ placement

15 preceeding

3 total dis­

placement from the optimal level

(1 —o ) 0 l+ 0 2

(14) AIt=odt -i+

459 (Referring to row in Table 2.)

9 7.02 13 (3.70) 14 -2 20 (The + in the D-column.) Should be volume differs interpret is assumed support [e,d] —Cl(-)/ r l( e domestic + 61

where is a measurement and/or optimization error and where and c( • ) is the estimated domestic volume, we would Excess inventory, i preceding excess inventory Ì2 — (1—0)01+02 Alt = —odt-1 + 7.02* (-3.70) +

(29)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 17 462 26 21 22 32 13 ambiquous ambiguous (18) 463 464 variance Hultzkrantz 50 standard error Hultkrantz 50:87-112 Comments

1 The restrictions referred to at the end of the first paragraph on page 449, are the adverse effects on the supply of delivered wood if the cartel raises the price of standing timber openly and early in the season.

2 The output price p, the price of pulp, is assumed to be constant and known by the buyers of wood (see p. 449). This is not a correct description of the actual behaviour of the pulp price — it is in fact highly volatile. On the other hand, the unexpected component of the output price can, in general, be considered to be captured by the random element in the wood supply equation, as the outcomes in the two variables become known to the buyer simultaneously. This is certainly so in the linear model estimated in this paper.

3 On page 451, it is mentioned that we, in a previous study, have rejected the hypothesis that the import supply of wood is infinitely elastic. If this hypothesis was true, we would expect the domestic price and quantity to be determined by the international price of wood, and not by the price of pulp, given that it is optimal to import any quantity at all. Only if imports are zero, will the price of pulp enter the domestic price and quantity equations. Because of border trade, imports will never be zero. Therefore, we hypothesized that the international price would be significant when the net import was positive (1975-85), and that the price of pulp would be significant when the net import was negative (1953-74). This hypothesis was rejected by the data; in fact it appeared as if the price of pulp was, in general, more significant than the international price. The following table is an abbreviation of Table 1 in Bergman and Löfgren (1988):

(30)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 18

Table A .l OLS estimates of pulpwood prices and quantities and standing timber prices, t-values within parentheses. Data and notation as in Paper fl], except r r for price of standing timber and s for price of sawtimber. Explanatory variables Time per. Dep. var const P r i d s R2 D -W 1953—74 r -38 .0009 .05 1.6 .15 .89 1.31 (-1.30) (0.05) (.20) (3.64) (1.03) 1975-85 r -121 .04 -.03 .67 .25 .69 1.82 (-.60) (2.13) (-.16) (.41) (2.61) 1953-74 rr -155 .04 .31 1.98 - .97 1.83 (-7.19) (3.13) (2.27) (5.81) 1975-85 rr -628 .04 .20 7.16 - .40 2.31 (-1.97) (1.29) (.67) (2.99) 1953-74 c 53 .0002 .04 -.31 .02 .75 1.64 (10.55) (.74) (.87) (-4.12) (.73) 1975-85 c 15 .0006 .01 -.15 .009 .77 3.12 (.60) (2.87) (.45) (-.75) (.77)

In Bergfors, Bergman and Hultkrantz (1988), it is shown that the average import prices paid by the Swedish industry differ substantially between exporting countries. This also contradicts the hypothesis of an infinitely elastic import supply.

4 We have excluded the capacity k and the shifter ps from equation (13), page 454, in order to simplify notation.

5 There are two data series available on fellings: one from the Forest Service, which is used in Paper [1], and one from the National Forest Survey, which is used in Paper [2]. At the time the papers were written, it was known that the latter had fairly large random errors (with a standard error of approximately 7 percent), while the former was thought to be quite accurate. Today, it is recognized that the Forest Service series also has quite large random errors, although smaller than those of the other series, as well as a systematic error that is probably larger than the systematic error of the National Forest Survev

(31)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 19

series. W ith hindsight, it would have been preferable to use the series from the National Forest Survey. The reason is that this series enables one to distin­ guish the forest industry’s own fellings from the fellings of other domestic agents. The industry’s own fellings can be used as an additional backstop, and it would have been valuable to use this information. However, the other series was chosen in the belief that that data was more accurate.

6 An alternative hypothesis that one could reasonably try to control for, is that the character of the import has changed. In the 1950s and 1960s, the small import (and export) was the result of border trade. In the 1970s and 1980s, the net import rose sharply, and more distant markets emerged as major suppliers of wood. However, this is exactly what Bergman and Löfgren (1988) tested for in the study referred to in comment 3, without finding any such differences.

7 In this paper, the production function of the industry is modelled as a function of the capacity and the input of wood only. This means that the cost of labour and energy will not enter the reduced forms. As the capacity is assumed to be fixed, the cost of capital will only enter the reduced forms from the supply side. A more orthodox model would allow the production to depend on the input of labour and energy as well, in which case we would have the reduced forms dependent on the wage and the price of energy. We made our choice of specification partly because of its simplicity and partly because it appeared to fit the data better. It could also be motivated by the fact that the pulp and paper industry’s costs for wood are typically at least twice as large as its costs for energy and labour combined.

(32)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 20

Paper [2] Differences in Final Felling and Thinning Behaviour Between Owner Categories in Sweden

Misprintings et cetera

Page Row(Eqv.) Stands Should be

269 17 Vaisanen, 1969 Vaisanen, 1970

18 1989, Clark, 1990). 1989; Clark, 1990; Reed & Clarke, 1990).

271 40 q} and q? the thin­

ning and final felling volumes

q} and q? the pulpwood and sawtimber volumes

274 16 labout labour

(17) aå = qi = qå = qi =

276 40 a positive function an increasing function

41 a negative function a decreasing function

277 Tab. 1 joint GLS reg­

ression analysis

restricted GLS estimates

279 35 significant insignificant

282 35 demand for timber demand of timber

39 Kikki

Vaisanen 1969

optimal policy for forest stands

Kilkki Vaisanen 1970

optimum cutting policy for the forest stand 40 102, 100-112 102, 1-23

46 optimal radiation optimal rotation

Comments

1 The two aims of the study mentioned in the introduction were to compare the behaviour of the different owner categories and to explain the swings in total final fellings and thinnings. However, much of the discussion in the results section and in the concluding remarks is devoted to a comparison with earlier work which directly studies the supply of pulpwood and sawtimber. The easiest solution to this disparity would have been to make the comparison a third aim. The differences in supply behaviour between owner categories could

(33)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 21

not be discussed at length, as the differences in behaviour were small and mostly insignificant. The most remarkable finding was, in fact, that the price response was so weak for all owner categories. As to an explanation for the development of final fellings and thinnings over time, the study suggests that this can, to a large extent, be explained by the changes in inventory.

2 The functional forms chosen for the estimation, eqs. (12*) to (15’) must of course be seen as first order approximations of the true relations. For example, the interest rate cannot enter the final felling and thinning equations additive-iy.

3 A possible explanation for the small and insignificant effects of prices on thinnings is that thinnings have been required by law, and the prescribed thinnings have probably often been larger than would have been chosen volun­ tarily.

4 A critical assumption of the paper is that there exists a stable relationship, i.e., the transformation function of (3.1) and (3.2), between the final felling and thinning volumes and the volumes of pulpwood and sawtimber. The statistical analysis supporting this assumption was not included in the paper, as perhaps it should have been. If we do not believe in a transformation func­ tion with fixed coefficients, our hypothesis must reasonably be, that a higher percentage of the thinnings and/or final fellings will be sold as pulpwood if the price of pulpwood rises relative to the price of sawtimber. The reason is that the forest owner can, to some extent, choose how to cut each log into pulp­ wood and sawtimber. The simplest test of the transformation function is, therefore, to enter this price ratio into equations (3.1) and (3.2). It turns out that the estimated parameter is positive, as we would expect according to the hypothesis, but insignificant. The t-values of the price ratio in the pulpwood equation are estimated to be 0.03 and 0.64 respectively, depending on whether we use the ‘add-to-one’ restriction or not. The corresponding t-values in the sawtimber equation are estimated to be 2.45 and 2.00, suggesting that the forest owners increase their ratio of sawtimber as the price of pulpwood in­ creases.

Another possibility is to make the coefficients a and ß dependent on the price ratio. This gives us the model

(34)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 22

q1 = a (p 7 p 2)xt + /3(p7P2)xf q2 = [i-û < p 7 p 2)]xt + [i—/?(pVp2)]xf

( A . l )

(A.2)

to estimate, where a (p 7 p 2) = do + <*i(p7p2) and /?(p7p2) =ßo + Æi(p7p2)> nsing the same notation as in Paper [2].

A related issue is the question of how the systematic errors of the two series on wood quantities affect the estimations. As discussed in comment 5 on Paper [1], there are such errors in both the thinning and final felling series from the National Forest Survey, and in the pulpwood and sawtimber series from the Forest Service. In the estimations presented in the paper, the transformation function is forced to pass through origo. The theoretical reasons for this restriction are quite obvious: the sum of the quantities of pulpwood and sawtimber must (almost) equal the sum of the quantities of final fellings and thinnings. The estimation procedure will be more efficient if a correct restriction is imposed. On the other hand, together with the systematic errors in the data series, this restriction may give rise to serial correlation. This can perhaps explain the low Durbin-Watson values. A serial correlation also biases the t-values upwards.

Besides estimating equations (A .l) and (A.2), which are subject to the ‘add-to-one’ restriction, we can estimate the corresponding equations without this restriction. In all cases, we may add a constant term, so as not to force the functions through origo. This gives us four alternative ways to estimate a system of equations, corres­ ponding to (A .l) and (A.2). Because of the restriction, this gives us 12 (and not 16) relevant estimates of a\ and ß\. In half of the cases, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the forest owners do not produce relatively more pulpwood, when the price of pulpwood is high relative to the price of sawtimber. In the other cases, we can reject the hypothesis at the 5 percent level. However, in three (out of six) instances, the sign is ‘wrong’, suggesting that the forest owners produce less pulp­ wood when its price is high. The following table shows the results when we apply the ‘add-to-one’ restriction, but allow the function not to pass through origo.

(35)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 23

Table A.2 Restricted GLS estimates of the resulting pulpwood supply from thinning and final felling, t-values within parenthesis. Data and notation as in Paper [2]. Explanatory variables Dep. var. con. xl xf (Pl/P 2)xt (p7p2)Xf D -W R 2 q1 -6.78 (-3.41) .90 .51 (3.02) (3.84) .06 (.25) .12 (.96) 1.69 .35

The estimates of ct\ and ß\ are both insignificantly positive. When the restriction of no constant term is lifted, the Durbin-Watson value increases and the t-values decrease, as expected. From the results of Table A.2, estimates of a and ß can be calculated. These are shown in Figure A .l, together with the price ratio between the prices of pulpwood and sawtimber, indexed so that the ratio equals 1 in 1970. Figure A .l Ratio of thinnings (alfa) and final fellings (beta) used as pulp­

wood, and the ratio of the prices of pulpwood and sawtimber (index: 1970 = 1), 1955 to 1987. 1.40 1.20 1.00 o 0. 80 0.60 p r ic e ratio alfa b e t a 0.40 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 Y e a r

(36)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 24

References

Anon., 1955—1987. Official Statistics o f Sweden, Manufacturing. The Central Bureau of Statistics, Stockholm.

Anon., 1955—1987. Yearbook o f Forest Statistics. National Board of Forestry, Jönköping.

Anon., 1992. Skogspolitiken inför 2000-talet (Forest Policy at the Prospect of the 21st Century). SOU 1992:77, p. 92, Allmänna Förlaget, Stockholm. (In Swedish.) Appelbaum, E. (1979). Testing Price Taking Behavior. Journal o f Econometrics 9, 283-294.

Appelbaum, E. (1982). The Estimation of the Degree of Oligopoly Power. Journal

o f Econometrics 19, 287—299.

Aronsson, T. (1990). The Short-R un Supply o f Roundwood Under Nonlinear

Income Taxation - Theory, Estimation Methods and Empirical Results Based on Swedish Data. Umeå Economic Studies No. 220, Umeå. Thesis.

Atkinson, S.E. and Kerkvliet, J. (1990). Dual Measures of Monopoly and Monop­ sony Power: An Application to Regulated Electric Utilities. Review o f Economics

and Statistics 2, 250—257.

Ausubel, L.M. and Deneckere, R.J. (1989). Reputation in Bargaining and Durable Goods Monopoly. Econometrica 57, 511—531.

Bagnoli, M., Salant, S.W. and Swierzbinski, J.E. (1989). Durable-Goods Monopoly with Discrete Demand. Journal o f Political Economy 97, 1459—1478.

Bain, J.S. (1951). Relation of Profit Rate to Industry Concentration: American Manufacturing, 1936—40. Quarterly Journal o f Economics 65, 293—324.

Baron, D. (1971). Demand Uncertainty in Imperfect Competition. International

Economic Review 12, 196—208.

Bartholomew, D.J. (1982). Stochastic Models for Social Processes. Third Edition, p. 7. John Wiley & Sons, Chichester.

Bergfors, U., Bergman, M.A. and Hultkrantz, L. (1988). Konkurrensen på den

svenska virkesmarknaden. Report No. 86, Department of Forest Economics, Swe­

dish University of Agricultural Sciences. (In Swedish.)

Bergman, M.A. (1988). Virkespriser och svensk virkesmarknad. Report No. 80, Department of Forest Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences. (In Swedish.)

Binkley, C.S. (1979). Timber Supply from Private Forests: An Econometric Analy­

sis o f Landowner Behaviour. Yale University. Thesis, pp. 72—74.

Bresnahan, T.F. (1989). Empirical Studies of Industries with Market Power. In: Schmalensee, R. and Willig, R. (eds.) Handbook o f Industrial Organization. Elsevier Science Publishing Company, Amsterdam.

(37)

M arket S tru ctu re and M arket P o w e r 25

Brännlund, R., Johansson, P.O. and Löfgren, K.G. (1985). An Econometric Analy­ sis of Aggregate Sawtimber and Pulpwood Supply in Sweden. Forest Science 31, 595-606.

Brännlund, R. (1988). The Swedish Roundwood Market - An Econometric Analy­

sis. Report No. 82, Department of Forest Economics, Swedish University of Agri­

cultural Sciences, Umeå. Thesis.

Brännlund, R. (1989). The Social Loss of Imperfect Competition: The Case of the Swedish Pulpwood Market. Scandinavian Journal o f Economics 91, 689—704. Bulow, J.I. (1982). Durable-Goods Monopolists. Journal o f Political Economy 90, 314-332.

Carlén, 0 . (1990). Private Nonindustrial Forest Owners' Management Behaviour:

An Econometric Analysis Based on Empirical Data. Report No. 92, Department of

Forest Economics, Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences, Umeå, pp.59—86. Clark, C.W. (1990). Mathematical Bioeconomics: The Optimal Management o f

Renewable Resources. Second Edition, pp. 39—44, 268—274. John Wiley k Sons,

New York.

Clarke, H.R. and Reed, W.R. (1989). The Tree-Cutting Problem in a Stochastic Environment: The Case of Age-Dependent Growth. Journal o f Economic Dyna­

mics and Control 13, 569—595.

Coase, R.H. (1972). Durability and Monopoly. Journal o f Law and Economics 15, 143-149.

Dasgupta, P.S. and Heal, G.M. (1979). Economic Theory and Exhaustible Re­ sources. pp. 334—336, Cambridge University Press, Oxford.

Diewert, W.E. (1973). Functional Forms for Profit and Transformation Functions.

Journal o f Economic Theory 6, 284—316.

Gul, F., Sonnenschein, H. and Wilson, R. (1986). Foundations of Dynamic Mono­ poly and the Coase Conjecture. Journal o f Economic Theory 39, 155—190.

Hetemäki, L. and Kuuluvainen, J. (1990) Supply and Demand for Pulpwood in

Finland. Department of Forest Economics, Finnish Forest Research Institute,

Helsinki. (Mimeographed.)

Hultkrantz, L. and Aronsson, T. (1989). Factors Affecting the Supply and Demand of Timber from Private Nonindustrial Lands in Sweden: An Econometric Study.

Forest Science 35, 946—961.

Johansson, P.O. and Löfgren, K.G. (1985). The Economics o f Forestry and Natu­

ral Economics, pp. 73—94, 112-165, 187—204. Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

Kilkki, P. and Väisänen, U. (1970). Determination of the Optimum Cutting Policy for the Forest Stand by Means of Dynamic Programming. Acta Forestalia Fennica

102, 1-23.

Kuuluvainen, J. (1989). Nonindustrial Private Timber Supply and Credit Rationing

- Microeconomic Foundations with Empirical Evidence from the Finnish Case.

Report No. 85, Department of Forest Economics, Swedish University of Agricultu­ ral Sciences, Umeå. Thesis, pp. 13-23, 133-189.

References

Related documents

Industrial Emissions Directive, supplemented by horizontal legislation (e.g., Framework Directives on Waste and Water, Emissions Trading System, etc) and guidance on operating

Given the pulp and paper industry’s economic importance and the residual emissions size, environmental work should, however, continue and focus on investigating the

Since supply depends on production cost as input prices for coffee beans and labor price, thus these variables can be as instrumental variables for price in the demand

But the amount of residual power produced, is always smaller than the total amount of power traded at Nord Pool, and while Nord Pool’s market share has increased significantly

Alexander Oskarsson ( Länsstyrelsen Västra Götaland; Arbetsförmedlingen caseworkers and administrators: Jack Jarschild ( came up with concept for labor market geared supplementary

(Cumbersome market conditions could also raise operating costs and entry barriers, preventing new firms from entering and supplying from reaching equilibrium level.) Therefore,

This paper examines competitive conditions on the Swedish banking market over the years 2006-2016, a time period where the number of Swedish banks has decreased at the same time

Keywords: option value, fuel price uncertainty, investment decision, pollution abatement, panel data, pulp and paper industry, energy and heating sector....