• No results found

MPRAPaperNo.39149,posted31.May2012/11:12 http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/39149/ lardalenUniversity/IndustrialEconomics30.May2012Onlineat Papahristodoulou,ChristosM ANLIPModelonWageDispersionandTeamPerformance MunichPersonalRePEcArchive

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "MPRAPaperNo.39149,posted31.May2012/11:12 http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/39149/ lardalenUniversity/IndustrialEconomics30.May2012Onlineat Papahristodoulou,ChristosM ANLIPModelonWageDispersionandTeamPerformance MunichPersonalRePEcArchive"

Copied!
18
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

MPRA

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

A NLIP Model on Wage Dispersion and

Team Performance

Papahristodoulou, Christos

M¨alardalen University/Industrial Economics

30. May 2012

Online at

http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/39149/

(2)

1

A N LIP Mod el on Wage Disp ersion and Team Perform ance

Christos Pap ahristod ou lou *

A bstract

Using a N on-Linear Integer Program m ing (N LIP) m od el, I exam ine if w age d ifferences betw een Su p er talents and N orm al p layers im prove the p erform ance of fou r team s w hich p articip ate in a tou rnam ent, su ch as in the UEFA Cham p ions Leagu e (UCL) grou p m atches. With ad -hoc w age d ifferences, the op tim al solutions of the m od el show that higher w age equ ality seem s to im p rove the p erform ance of all team s, irresp ectively if the elasticity of su bstitu tion betw een Sup er- and N orm al- p layers is high or low . In ad d ition to that, a U -typ e p erform ance exists in tw o team s w ith the highest and the second high elasticity of su bstitu tion. With team d ata from the 2011-12 UCL grou p m atches and from the Italian Serie A over 2010-12 seasons, the w age d isp ersion has no effect on team p erform ances.

Keyw ord s: Players, Team s, Wages, Perform ance, Tou rnam ent

*Dep artm ent of Ind u strial Econom ics & Organization, Mälard alen University , Västerås, Sw ed en; christos.p ap ahristod ou lou @m d h.se Tel; +4621543176

(3)

2

1. Introduction

The op tim al w age stru ctu re of team s has been frequ ently d iscu ssed over the last d ecad es. The m ain hyp othesis is w hether the com p ressed or the d isp ersed w ages among a team’s players have a stronger impact on the p erformance of the team. As is very often in econom ics, there are at least tw o schools of thou ght. Lazear & Rosen (1981) argu ed that the team p erform ance in creases if the best talents are p aid higher w ages than the norm al p layers. Milgrom (1988) and Lazear (1989) on the other hand , stressed the p ossibility of bad field coop eration betw een p layers, and consequ ently the p erform ance cou ld be inferior, if the u n d er-p aid p layers feel d iscrim inated . Levine (1991) took an extrem e position and favou red the egalitarian w ages. Fehr and Schm id t (1999) tried to balance these tw o effects and argu ed that, as a w hole, the team losses m ore if w ages are m ore u nequ al than equ a l.

Franck & N ü esch (2007) review ed the em p irical stu d ies from sp ort team s, in baseball, hockey, basket and football. Som e stu d ies seem to su p p ort the com p ressed w ages hyp othesis. They argu e that these find ings can p artly be exp lained becau se the m ajority of em p irical stu d ies assu m e a linear relationship betw een w age d isp ersion and team p erform ance. In their ow n stu d y, based on 5281 ind ivid u al salary p roxies from Germ an soccer players betw een 1995-07, they allow ed for squ ares of the Gini coefficient and th e coefficient of variation of the w age d istribu tion a t the beginning of the season. They fou nd a U-form ed sp ortive su ccess, i.e. team s p erform better by either an egalitarian pay stru ctu re or a steep one1. On the other hand , Pokorny (2004) fou nd an inverted U-form ed su ccess, i.e. the p erform ance is higher w ith interm ed iate w age d ifferences. Avru tin & Som m ers (2007), u sing baseball d ata from 2001-05, fou nd no effect. Torgler et al (2008), u sing also d ata from the Germ an Bu nd esliga (and the N BA), fou nd that p layers care m ore abou t the salary d istribu tion w ithin the team and not ju st abou t their ow n salary. Generally, p layers p refer a red u ced inequ ality and in that case their p erform ance im p roves. In ad d ition, a d etailed investigation of the basketball d ata sho w s also that w hen a p layer m oves from a relative incom e ad vantage to a relative d isad vantage, his p erform ance d ecreases in a statistically significant w ay. On the other hand , m oving from relative incom e d isad vantage to relative ad vantage has no effects. Wisem an & Chatterjee (2003), u sing baseball d ata from 1980-02, fou nd a negative effect of w age d isp ersion. In a sim ilar stu d y recently, i.e. w ith baseball d ata from 1985-10, Breu nig et al (2012) fou nd also a negative effect of w age d isp ersion. On the other h and , Sim m ons & Berri (2011), u sing basket statistics, su p p orted the Lazear & Rosen (1981) hyp othesis that higher w age d isp ersion increases team p erform ance.

1 Also they found evidence that teams with dispersed wages entertain the public better since the

(4)

3

In this p ap er I form u late and solve a N LIP m od el to exam ine m ainly the effects of w age d ifferences betw een Su p er (S) - and N orm al (N ) - p layers in the p erform ance of fou r team s, w hich p articip ate in a tournam ent like the UEFA Cham p ions Leagu e (UCL) grou p m atches. Using ad -hoc w age d ifferences and variou s “team p rod u ction functions”, it is of interest to see if the optimal solutions favour the compressed or the d isp ersed w ages hyp otheses for all, or som e team s. In ad d ition, tw o sm all d ata sets (UCL grou p m atches from 2011-12 and Italian Serie A from 2010-12 seasons) are u sed to test the above hyp otheses.

2.1 The model

There are fou r football team s w hich p lay three hom e and three aw ay m atches in the grou p stage of the UCL tou rnam ent. As a w hole there are 12 m atches and the m axim u m nu m ber of p oints is 36. The tw o team s w hich collect m ost p oints are qu alified for the next rou nd and the other tw o are elim inated2.

The fou r p articip ating team s have d ifferent qu alities and consequ ently d ifferent ranking. To differentiate the teams, four different “team production functions” are assu m ed . I follow Kesenne (2007) and assu m e that the form ation of the team s consists of a certain nu m ber of S- and N -p layers. The S- and N -p layers are consid ered as being from alm ost com p lem ents, to alm ost su bstitu tes. All S-p layers are equally “Super” and all N -players are equally “Normal”3

. Team s u se their S- and N - p layers in ord er to “p rod u ce” p oints. The su p p ly of S- and N -p layers is u nlim ited . Since the valu e of the m arginal p rod u ct of p layers can’t be observed or m easu red , team s have a certain w age stru ctu re, from very d isp ersed t o very com p ressed . The w ages is the p olicy variable of the m od el. It is assu m ed that team s have no other fixed costs (like m anagers or other facilities); their only variable costs consist of the w ages they p ay to their p layers. It is also assu m ed that all team s receive sim ilar revenu es, either d irectly from UEFA, and / or from their p u blic, TV-rights and sp onsors and the w ages they p ay can’t be higher than their revenu es. All team s p lay a “Cou rnot” typ e gam e and m axim ize sim u ltaneou sly their p oints.

The m od el is rather general and can exp lain, not only the ow n p erform ance, bu t the effect to the other team s as w ell, even if they keep their w ages u nchanged . It can also

2

The third team continu es in the UEFA Eu rop a Leagu e.

3

Obviou sly, there are p layers w ho, objectively, belong to one category or the other. Perhap s, m ost p layers are neither that excellent to be classified in the first category, n or that “N orm al” to be

classified in the second category. In the football w orld , it is very com m on that the su p p orters of a team tend to overvalue their ow n players and und ervalue the competitor’s players. This is an emp irical issu e, left to su p p orters, to m anagers, to jou rnalists or even to those w ho d o research in efficiency analysis.

(5)

4

show w hether the tou rnam ent rem ains balanced and w hether team s w ho have m ore S-p layers can collect m ore p oints.

Let P1, P2, P3, P4, be the p oints collected by the team s; let S1, S2, S3, S4, be the nu m ber of S-p layers, and N1, N2, N3, N4 the nu m ber of N -p layers the team s u se in these m atches. Let w1, w2, w3, w4, be the victories of the team s, d1, d2, d3, d4, the d raw m atches and l1, l2, l3, l4, the losses (d efeats) of the team s. All these 24 variables are p ositive integers.

Since all firm s aim at m axim izing p oints (sim u ltaneou sly), their objective fu nction is given by (1), u nd er the follow ing constraints.

The key constraints that differentiate teams are the teams’ “production” functions , (2a – 2d ). All fu nctions are of Constant Elasticity of Su bstitu tio n (CES) typ e of d egree one, w ith d ifferent elasticity. The fu nction of team 1 is closed to Leontief, i.e. very low elasticity of su bstitu tion betw een its S- and N -p layers4. Team 4 on the other hand , has a closed to Cobb-Dou glas “p rod u ction” fu nction, i.e. alm ost excellent elasticity of su bstitu tion, team 2 is close to team 1, w hile team 3 is close to team 4. The u se of S- and N -p layers for each team w ill be end ogenou sly d eterm ined from the op tim al solu tion. When the team form ation has been d eterm ined , it is assu m ed that the sam e team w ill be u sed for all six m atches, u nless the w age stru ctu re ha s changed . Team s of cou rse change the com p osition of their p layers for tactical reasons, su ch as if they p lay aw ay against a stronger team or if they p lay at hom e against a w eaker team , or becau se som e of their p layers m ight be inju red or p u nished and are not available for a p articu lar m atch. The m od el neglects su ch p ossibilities. The m od el also assu m es that p layers w ho are not u sed (becau se the roster of team s consists of m ore than 11 p layers), receive zero w ages. N otice that, d u e to the integer constraint of p layers, the com p osition of the team can rem ain u nchanged , even if the w ages change. ti is the efficiency p aram eter and ai is the d istribu tion p aram eter .

Constraints (3a – 3d ) restrict the nu m ber of team p layers to 11. In reality, even for top and w ealthy team s, the nu m ber of S- is often low er than the nu m ber of N -p layers, w hich is given by constraints (4a – 4d ). Desp ite the fact, that su ch cond ition is not necessary, it is stated exp licitly in ord er to sp eed u p the solu tion of this com p lex m od el.

As is w ell know n, victories are w orth 3 p oints; d raw s are w orth 1 p oint and losses, zero p oints. Thu s, the nu m ber of p oints collected to every team is given by constraints (5a – 5d ).

4

In reality, an S-p layer can su bstitu te an N -p layer m ore easily than the reverse. I assu m e that the elasticity of su bstitu tion is u nch anged , irresp ectively if the S- su bstitu tes the N -p layer, or if the N - su bstitu tes the S-p layer.

(6)

5

parameters wage w w t j i j i Binary d d w w Integer l d w N S P d a N w S w P P P d a P d a l d w d a w w w d a d d d l a pairwise d w w l a pairwise d w w d a d w P d a N S d a N S N S t P d a N S t P N S t P N S t P t s P i i i i N S i i a i j h j i a i j h j i i i i i i i i N i S i i i i i i i i i i a j i h j i i a j i h j i a i j a i j h j i h j i a i j h j i i i i i i i i i i                                                     

              , 1 0 0 , 4 ,.., 1 , ) , , , ( ) , , , , ( ) 13 13 ( , 0 5 . 0 12 ) 12 ( , 36 ) 11 11 ( , 18 ) 10 10 ( , 6 ) 9 9 ( , ) 8 8 ( , ) 7 7 ( , , 1 ) 6 6 ( , , 1 ) 5 5 ( 3 ) 4 4 ( ) 3 3 ( 11 ) 1 ( ) 2 2 ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( ) 1 ( . . ) 1 ( max , , , , 2 4 1 , , , , , , , , , , 1 . 0 1 1 . 0 4 4 1 . 0 4 4 4 4 5 . 0 1 5 . 0 3 3 5 . 0 3 3 3 3 10 1 10 2 2 10 2 2 2 2 100 1 100 1 1 100 1 1 1 1 4 1             

Each one of the 12 m atches in the grou p of fou r team s, end s either w ith a hom e team victory,wih,j,w ith an aw ay team victory,waj,i,or w ith a hom e team d raw ,dih,j,w hich is obviou sly equ al to the aw ay team d raw ,daj,i. Bu t, in ord er to id entify the correct p air of team s w hich p lay d raw at hom e and / or d raw aw ay , w e m u st sep arate the hom e team d raw from the aw ay team d raw , i.e. w e need 24 ad d itional constraints (6a – 7l). The first 12 constraints (6a – 6l) relate each p air of team s to hom e team d r aw and the rem aining 12, (7a – 7l), relate to the aw ay team d raw . If for instance d1h,2 1,(and consequ entlyw1h,2w2a,1 0), from constraints (6a) and (7a) w e are ensu red that

, 1 1 , 2  a

d as w ell. If that m atch end s w ith a hom e or aw ay victory, it im p lies that . 0 1 , 2 2 , 1   a h d

(7)

6

m atch resu lts, su ch as d1h,2d2a,10.5 and w1h,2w2a,1 0.25. Therefore we require that all p ossible m atch resu lts are binary as w ell.

Obviou sly, the d raw s (and the victories) for each team is the su m of all p ossible d raw s (and victories) against all other team s. Constraints (8a – 8d ) ensu re that the nu m ber of d raw s in constraints is alw ays an integer (and actu ally even) nu m ber, or zero. For instance, w hen team 1 p lays only one m atch d raw , it is d11.If the d raw m atch w as a hom e m atch against team 2, it m u st be d1h,2 1,(from 8a), and 1,

1 , 2 

a d

(from 8b), as w ell. In that case, if team 2 d oes not p lay another m atch d raw , it m u st be d2 1as w ell. Of cou rse, if team 2 p lays three d raw m atches, i.e. d2 3,it im p lies that team 2 m u st have p layed d raw against the other team s as w ell. A sim ilar interp retation ap p lies for the victory constraints (9a – 9d ).

Since each team p lay six m atches, there are 6 p ossible resu lts from its gam es, i.e. constraints (10a – 10d ) are requ ired . Constraints (11a – 11d ) show that no team can collect m ore than 18 p oints. In ad d ition to that, constraint (12) show s that the m axim u m nu m ber of p oints from all m atches is 36, com p osed w ith 12 victories (for tw o team s) and 12 d efeats for the other tw o team s.

Finally, constraints (13a – 13d ) ensu re non-negative profits. The revenu e fu nction is qu ad ratic in the p oints collected . All team s p ay the sam e, higher w ages to their S-p layers, and the sam e, low er w ages to their N -S-p layers. The initial S-p aram eters are:

8  i S w and 4.8, i N

w i.e. the N -p layers receive only 60% of the S-p layers’ w ages. Keep ing 8

i

S

w , the m od el is rep eated and solved for higher and low er valu es of the p aram eter .

i

N

w Obviou sly the w age d isp ersion or com p ression d oes not influ ence the p erform ance of the ow n team , bu t the p erform ances of the other team s too. The non-negative p rofits constraints are satisfied if each team collects at least 6 p oints. With less than 6 p oints there is no integer valu e of N - and S-p layers to ensu re non -negative p rofits.

The m od el is now com p lete and w as solved in Lingo, u sing Global Solver.

2.2 The Solution

I solved the m od el 124 tim es, i.e. 31 tim es per team , u sing 31 d ifferent ,

i

N

w starting from as low as 3.4 u p to 6.4, increased at a range of 0.1. When one team changed its

,

i

N

w all other team s keep their ow n

i N w u nchanged . When 6.4, i N w there is no feasible (integer) solu tion, becau se the non -negative p rofits constraint(s) are violated .

(8)

7

Table 1 d ep icts the ow n effects5 on p erform ance and team com p osition, w here the p olicy variable is

i

N

w . Som e p oints from the Table 1 are w orth m entioned .

The initial solu tion, w ith 8

i

S

w and 4.8,

i

N

w show s that the tou rnam ent is com p letely balanced , becau se each team w ins its three hom e m atches and collects 9 points. Despite the differences in their “production” functions, all four teams have a sim ilar team com p osition, consisting of 1 S-p layer and 10 N -p layers and each team m akes a p rofit of 11.5.

Table 1: Points m axim ization, su bject to non -negative p rofits i N w S1 N1 P1  S2 N2 P22 S3 N3 P33 S4 N4 P44 3.4 1 10 6 0.55 1 10 6 0.43 3 8 6 0.5 1 10 9 0.78 3.5 1 10 6 0.5 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.89 1 10 9 0.74 3.6 1 10 6 0.34 1 10 6 0.5 1 10 9 0.65 3 8 9 0.01 3.7 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 6 0.01 3 8 6 0.65 1 10 9 0.28 3.8 1 10 9 0.66 1 10 6 0.29 2 9 6 0.5 2 9 6 0.5 3.9 1 10 9 0.66 2 9 6 0.48 1 10 9 0.48 2 9 6 0.65 4.0 1 10 9 0.5 2 9 6 0.01 3 8 9 0.65 1 10 6 0.01 4.1 1 10 6 0.37 4 7 9 0.44 5 6 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.45 4.2 1 10 9 0.37 1 10 6 0.30 1 10 6 0.03 1 10 6 0.4 4.3 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 6 0.66 1 10 6 0.72 1 10 6 0.5 4.4 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.37 1 10 6 0.01 1 10 6 0.61 4.5 1 10 9 0.02 1 10 6 0.44 5 6 9 0.65 5 6 9 0.5 4.6 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 6 0.44 1 10 6 0.5 1 10 6 0.5 4.7 1 10 9 0.66 1 10 9 0.5 4 7 9 0.5 4 7 9 0.65 4.8 1 10 9 0.34 1 10 9 0.36 1 10 9 0.57 1 10 9 0.67 4.9 1 10 9 0.66 4 7 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.89 1 10 9 0.74 5.0 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.44 1 10 9 0.5 4 7 9 0.65 5.1 1 10 9 0.34 1 10 9 0.01 1 10 9 0.99 3 8 9 0.8 5.2 1 10 9 0.66 1 10 9 0.34 2 9 9 0.02 1 10 9 0.03 5.3 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.37 1 10 9 0.01 1 10 9 0.62 5.4 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.5 2 9 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.01 5.5 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.65 1 10 9 0.43 1 10 9 0.5 5.6 1 10 9 0.5 2 9 9 0.76 1 10 9 0.65 1 10 9 0.78 5.7 1 10 9 0.66 1 10 9 0.5 2 9 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.03 5.8 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.65 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.68 5.9 1 10 9 0.5 1 10 9 0.65 1 10 9 0.63 1 10 9 0.02 6.0 1 10 12 0.5 2 9 10 0.65 1 10 10 0.62 1 10 12 0.5 6.1 1 10 10 0.21 2 9 12 0.44 1 10 10 0.99 1 10 12 0.99 6.2 1 10 10 0.55 1 10 10 0.5 2 9 12 0.71 1 10 10 0.72 6.3 1 10 12 0.44 1 10 12 0.5 1 10 12 0.65 1 10 12 0.21 6.4 1 10 12 0.11 1 10 12 0.2 1 10 12 0.5 1 10 12 0.5 5

To save sp ace, I have exclu d ed the cross effects, i.e. effects on o ther team s. The fou r ad d itional Tables can be p rovid ed by the au thor at a requ est.

(9)

8

As exp ected , team 1 (closed to Leontief), never changes its team com p osition and u ses 1 S- and 10 N -p layers. On the other hand , it is team 3 that changes its team com p osition m ore frequ ent (in 11 ou t of 31 tim es) and not team 4, (closed to Cobb-Dou glas).

The m ost striking resu lt is that m ore S-p layers d o not alw ays increase the p erform ance of team s! This is d u e to tw o reasons. First, other team s m ight also p lay w ith m ore S-p layers too. Second the efficiency6 of the team s changes too. For instance, w hen wN4 4.7,both team 4 and team 2 u se 7 N -p layers and all team s collect 9 p oints and their resp ective efficiencies are alm ost sim ilar, t443.6, t2 38.6.

When wN4 6.0, both team s u se 10 N -p layers, team 4 collects 12 p oints, w hile team 2 collects 7 p oints, becau se their new efficiencies are t4 35.5, t2 7.5. Obviou sly, w hen the p erform ance d oes not increase, the p rofits of the team s are red u ced w ith m ore S-p layers. And the p oints collected p er team are not related to their d istribu tion p aram eter of p layers’ ai.

Finally, the tou rnam ent ap p ears to be frequ ently balanced . For instance, it is com p leted balanced in 23/ 31 cases w hen team 1 selects w ages; it is also com p letely balanced in 16/ 31 cases w hen team 2 selects w ages, and in 19/ 31 cases w hen team 3 or team 4 select w ages. And w hile in m ost cases the total nu m ber of p oints selected equ als to 36, there are som e d raw m atches w ith a total nu m ber of points equ al to 35 (alw ays w hen 6.0

i

N

w ).

2.2.1 The regressions from the optimal solutions

(i) The ow n effects

In ord er to find ou t how the w age d isp ersion influ ences the p erform ance of the team s, I ru n the follow ing tw o regression equ ations, based on all 124 op tim al solu tions. 2 2 1 1 ) 8 ( ) 8 ( ) 8 ( i i i N N i N i w w P w P              .

The right hand sid e variable is the w age d ifference betw een the resp ective fixed

8  i S w and i N

w , w hile the d ep end ant variable is p oints collected . N egative (p ositive) -estim ates im p ly that the p erform ance of team s im p roves if the w age equ ality (inequ ality) betw een the S- and N -p layers increases. Sim ilarly, negative -estim ates

6

(10)

9

and p ositive -estim ates im p ly a U-typ e su ccess, i.e. either highly u nequ al or highly equ al w ages w ill im p rove p erform ance.

Table 2a su m m arizes the regression estim ates for every team . Based on the average nu m ber of p oints, team 1 and 4 are qu alified . It is clear that in the linear m od el, all team s im p rove their p erform ances w hen the w age d isp ersion d ecreases (all  -estim ates are strongly negative). Consequ ently, the find ings su p p ort the Milgrom (1988) and Lazear (1989) hyp othesis.

Table 2a: OLS ow n estim ates Team 1 47 . 1 97 . 8    P Team 2 89 . 1 39 . 8    P Team 3 72 . 1 68 . 8    P Team 4 80 . 1 74 . 8    P  12.65** (19.24) 13.6** (18.52) 12.75** (15.64) 12.77** (14.16)  -1.19** (-5.84) -1.68** (-7.39) -1.32** (-5.20) -1.30** (-4.65) 2 R 0.52 0.64 0.46 0.41  12.97** (5.44) 17.25** (6.73) 18.36** (6.70) 21.7** (7.88)  -1.41 (-0.87) -4.25* (-2.43) -5.26** (-2.82) -7.58** (-4.04)  0.036 (0.14) 0.414 (1.48) 0.637* (2.13) 1.01** (3.38) 2 R 0.51 0.66 0.52 0.56

** significant at 0.01 level; * significant at 0.05 level; t -statistics is in p arentheses

Regard ing the qu ad ratic fu nction, the U-typ e su ccess for team s 3 and 4 is not rejected , over the relevant range (3.4,...,6.4).

i

N

w For instance, team 3 w ill m inim ize its p erform ance and collect abou t 7.5 p oints if it p ays 3.9,

3 

N

w (i.e. if its N -p layers receive slightly less than 50% of the S-p layers w ages), it w ill collect abou t 8.5 p oints if it p ays the low est w age 3.4

3 

N

w and it w ill collect abou t 11.5 p oints if it p ays the u p p er-lim it w age 6.4.

3 

N

w Sim ilarly, team 4 w ill m inim ize its selected p oints (7.5), if it p ays 4.25

4 

N

w .

(ii) The cross effects

In ord er to find ou t the p erform ance effects to the other team s, I ru n the follow ing tw o regression equ ations:

j i w w P w P j j j N N i N i          , ) 8 ( ) 8 ( ) 8 ( 2 2 1 1     

(11)

10

The estim ates are given in Table 2b. In the linear m od el, the estim ates are com p letely consistent w ith those in Table 2a. A d ecrease of w age d isp ersion in team i red u ces the p erform ance of team j (all -estim ates are strongly p ositive).

Table 2b: OLS cross estim ates

Linear Quadratic   2 R    R2 Effect on Team 2 Team 1 7.19** (12.2) 0.64** (3.48) 0.27 9.08** (4.3) -0.69 (-0.5) 0.22 (1.14) 0.27 Effect on Team 3 8.20** (27.1) 0.22* (2.32) 0.13 5.87** (5.89) 1.85** (2.74) -0.26* (-2.43) 0.26 Effect on Team 4 6.99** (14.8) 0.59** (4.1) 0.34 4.57** (2.78) 2.3* (2.05) -0.27 (-1.53) 0.37 Effect on Team 1 Team 2 6.95** (13.2) 0.66** (4.05) 0.34 7.5** (3.93) 0.28 (0.2) 0.06 (0.3) 0.32 Effect on Team 3 6.87** (11.9) 0.66** (3.73) 0.30 2.61 (1.37) 3.66** (2.81) -0.48* (-2.32) 0.39 Effect on Team 4 7.60** (9.95) 0.62* (2.60) 0.16 5.14 (1.88) 2.35 (1.27) -0.28 (-0.94) 0.16 Effect on Team 1 Team 3 6.83** (9.21) 0.85** (3.69) 0.30 5.88* (2.20) 1.51 (0.83) -0.11 (-0.37) 0.27 Effect on Team 2 8.15** (27.3) 0.23* (2.53) 0.15 5.24** (5.72) 2.28** (3.66) -0.33** (-3.3) 0.37 Effect on Team 4 7.3** (14.3) 0.49** (3.13) 0.23 3.0 (1.82) 3.52** (3.13) -0.49* (-2.7) 0.37 Effect on Team 1 Team 4 7.91** (17.5) 0.34* (2.45) 0.14 6.59** (4.08) 1.27 (1.16) -0.15 (-0.8) 0.14 Effect on Team 2 7.57** (11.0) 0.49* (2.30) 0.13 1.37 (0.63) 4.86** (3.28) -0.7** (-2.97) 0.31 Effect on Team 3 6.78** (10.3) 0.73** (3.56) 0.28 2.84 (1.26) 3.5* (2.28) -0.45 (-1.82) 0.33

In the qu ad ratic m od el, som e estim ates are consistent w ith those in Table 2a, becau se a reversed U-typ e su ccess ap p ears. For instance, w hen team 3 p ays 6.4,

3 

N

w w hile

team 2 keep s its initial w ages at 4.8,

2 

N

(12)

11

w ou ld collect 11.5 p oints. The p air of team s (first entry d enotes w age d isp ersion of team i and second entry d enotes the p erform ance of team j) w ith a reversed U-typ e p erform ance are: (1, 3), (2, 3), (3, 2), (3, 4) and (4, 3), w hile in the rem aining seven p airs, there is no effect. N otice that team 3, w hich im p roves its ow n p erform ance by low or high w age d isp ersion (Table 2a), is affected negatively by all other team s too. To su m m arize the estim ates, w e conclu d e that team 1 (w ith the alm ost Leontief typ e), w hich collects the highest average nu m ber of p oints (8.97), im p roves its ow n p erform ance linearly w ith low er w age d isp ersion. And d esp ite the fact that the U-form ed w age d isp ersion d oes not im p rov e its ow n p erU-form ance, it is the only team that is not influ enced from low or high w age d isp ersions of other team s.

3. Empirical study

Obviou sly, to test the sam e hyp otheses w ith real d ata is alm ost im p o ssible, becau se there are many problems with the observed players’ wages and of course the team form ation. It w ill requ ire a hu ge am ou nt of tim e to refine all available d ata set by observing each ind ivid u al p layer , to exam ine if he w as inju red or p u nished and u navailable for som e m atches, or if he p layed only a sm all p art in a m atch. And even if su ch inform ation w ere relatively easy to collect, the w age d isp ersion of the team w ou ld vary d ep end ing u p on the various w eights one u ses for each p layer p articip ation in the m atches. To ad hoc exclu d e som e p layers (often the you ngsters w ith low w ages) m ight be erroneou s too, becau se som etim es m anagers d o not p lay the “expensive” players and deliberately use “cheap” players in some matches. Tw o very sm all d ata sets have been collected , assu m ing sim p ly that all p layers, for w hom w age observations exist, are available to p lay, and all p layers’ w ages have th e sam e w eights, irresp ectively if they p layed or not. The team sp irit or the envy of p layers exists for the entir e team roster and not necessarily for those p layers w ho are field ed . The first d ata set consists of 32 Eu rop ean team s (496 p layers) from 48 UCL grou p m atches, p layed in 2011. The aggregate statistics are show n in Ap p end ix (Table A). As is show n, for som e team s there are accu rate observations for at m ost 10-13 p layers. The second d ata set consists of 40 Italian team s from the Serie A (abou t 1015 p layers), over tw o seasons 2010-11/ 2011-12, obtained from the follow ing sites: http :/ / w w w .football-m arketing.com / 2010/ 09/ 07/ italian -serie-a-w age-list/ ,

http :/ / w w w .xtratim e.org/ foru m / show thread .p hp ?t=261972. N otice that 34 of these Italian team s ap p ear in both seasons, w hile the rem aining 6 team s ap p ear only in one season (3 of them relegated in the first season and 3 of them ad vanced in the second season). Since the team roster of these 34 team s change and / or som e w age contracts are re-negotiated , the w age d isp ersion w ithin the sam e team varies from year to year.

(13)

12

Table 3 su m m arizes the OLS estim ates for these d ata sets. In UCL, the w age d isp ersion is m easu red by Coefficient of Variation (CV) and by Mean Absolu te Deviation (MAD) as w ell; as control variables, tw o d ifferent p roxies are u sed , the team valu e (V) and the resp ective UEFA r anking (R); in Serie A, the w age d isp ersion is also m easu red by CV and by Coefficient of Disp ersion (CD) w hile as a control variable the average w age (W) p er team is u sed .

In case (i), the nu m ber of p oints d oes not au tom atically reflect qu alification or elim ination from the tou rnam ent, becau se it d ep end s on the grou p . For instance in grou p D, the elim inated third team ’s p oints (Ajax) are id entical to the second team ’s (Lyon), bu t Lyon had a better goal d ifference against Ajax. Sim ilarly, w hile Manchester City elim inated w ith 10 p oints, fou r other team s in other grou p s qu alified w ith less p oints. Consequ ently, in case (ii), a d u m m y variable w as introd u ced w ith the follow ing valu es: 1 for the tw o qu alified team s p er grou p ; 0.5 for the third elim inated team and 0 for the fou rth team .

Table 3: OLS estim ates for UCL and Serie A

UCL: (i) Point s

   2 R    R2 M A D V CV V 4.205** (4.50) 1.775 (0.78) 0.014 (1.89) 0.45 4.66** (2.61) -0.45 (-0.09) 0.02** (4.91) 0.44 M A D R CV R 3.066** (2.66) 3.056 (1.93) 0.044* (2.16) 0.47 2.14 (1.12) 2.865 (0.6) 0.07** (4.60) 0.41

UCL: (ii) (Dummy )*(Point s)

M A D V CV V 2.24 (1.79) 4.37 (1.45) 0.008 (0.75) 0.35 1.72 (0.74) 2.76 (0.42) 0.02** (3.61) 0.30 M A D R CV R 0.64 (0.43) 3.52 (1.73) 0.051 (1.95) 0.41 -1.13 (-0.47) 5.55 (0.92) 0.08** (4.17) 0.37

It alian Serie A: Point s

CD W CV W 42.73** (6.81) -0.08 (-0.68) 14.34** (5.99) 0.50 43.49** (6.49) -0.08 (-0.62) 14.44** (6.01) 0.50

** significant at 0.01 level; * significant at 0.05 level; t -statistics is in p arentheses.

Both d ata sets show sim ilar estim ates, w ith rather low exp lana tory p ow er. N one of the d isp ersion variables is statistically significant from zer o. On the other hand , as exp ected , stronger or richer team s p erform bet ter. Moreover, since both sam p les are very sm all and the p layers’ statistics are not refined , it is d ifficu lt to d raw certain conclu sions.

(14)

13

4. Conclusions

The p u rp ose of this p ap er w as to d evelop a kind of “general equ ilibriu m ” m od el to investigate if team s p erform better or w orse w hen they p ay rather com p ress ed or m ore d isp ersed w ages to their S- and N - qu ality p layers. In the m od el, fou r d ifferent football team s com p ete, in a tou rnam ent like the U CL grou p m atches, to m axim ize their p oints and qu alify in the next grou nd . Som e key featu res of the m od el are the non-linearity of “p rod u ction” fu nctions (w hich are of CES typ e w ith d ifferent elasticity of su bstitu tion am ong p layers) and a nu m ber of various integer variables (like p layers, p oints, victories and d raw s). Assu m ing a high w age level for the im p licitly solved S-qu ality p layers in every team and a rather large range of low er w ages for the im p licitly solved N -qu ality p layers, global optim al solu tions w ere obtained .

In m ost cases, the team form ation is com p osed by 1 S- and 10 N -p layers. Moreover, as it often hap p ens in football, team s w hich field m ore S- p layers d o not alw ays p erform better than team s w ith ju st 1 S-p layer! This is m ainly d u e to d ifferences in absolu te and / or relative efficiency the team s.

Desp ite the fact that all fou r team s p erform alm ost equ ally w ell and the w age p aram eters lead to a rather balanced tou rnam ent, team 1, w ith the low est elasticity of su bstitu tion betw een S- and N - p layers, collects on average, slightly m ore p oints than all others (follow ed by team 4, w ith the highest elasticity of su bstitu t ion).

Using the collected p oints from the resp ective op tim al solu tions, linear and qu ad ratic regressions w ere ru n to exam ine the w age d isp ersion on (i) the ow n effects and (ii) the cross effects. All fou r team s im p rove their ow n p erform ance if the w age d isp ersion d ecreases. In m ost cases, the d ecrease in w age d isp ersion d eteriorates the p erform ance of other team s as w ell. In ad d ition, som e evid ence on the U-typ e ow n su ccess and a reverse U-typ e cross su ccess ap p ears. Consequ ently, w hile highly d ep ressed w ages im p rove p erform ances linearly, interm ed iary w age d isp ersion is w orse than a highly d isp ersed one.

On the other hand , u sing tw o sm all d ata sets, from the UCL and the Italian Serie A, the observed w age d isp ersion from all p layers of the team s w as not statistically significant from zero, w hen other controlled variables (like the ranking or the valu e of team s) w ere inclu d ed in the regressions.

The m od el can be easily extend ed to catch other im p ortant asp ects. For instance, instead of m axim izing p oints, su bject to non -negative p rofits, team s can m axim ize p rofits. One can also increase the “p rice” p aram eter of p oints from 12 to 15, so that team s can collect m ore than 12 p oints that som e global solu tions p rovid ed . Another

(15)

14

interesting extension can be to allow d ifferent team s com p ositions in d ifferent matches, or combine the “production” functions per match, to find out if the “Leontief team” beats or is defeated by the “Cobb-Douglas team”, at home or away, and try to collect ap p rop riate m atch d ata to test the d erived hypothesis. Finally, since the selected CES fu nctions d o not let team s u se variou s tactical d isp ositions of p layers, it w ou ld be d esirable to stress the field p ositions of the S- and N -p layers. That can be sim ilar in sp irit to H irotsu & W right (2006), w ho ap p lied a N ash -Cou rnot gam e to figu re ou t the w in p robabilities of the 4-4-2 strategy over the 4-5-1 one.

(16)

15

Table A: MAD, CV, UEFA Ranking, Team valu e in m . of € and Points

Teams per group Observed players MAD (1) CV (2) Rank (3) Value (4) Points (5) FC Bayern 24 1.8196 0.5517 122.507 359.95 13 N ap oli 24 0.4203 0.6453 39.853 194.2 11 Man. City 16 1.3656 0.3051 61.507 467.0 10 Villarreal 16 0.2875 0.3647 78.551 142.6 0 Inter 26 1.3231 0.6479 102.853 246.85 10 CSKA 16 0.2625 0.2153 80.566 137.3 8 Trabzonsp or 13 0.2793 0.3130 20.115 87.8 7 Lille 13 0.3562 0.2580 38.802 119.75 6 Benfica 16 0.2672 0.2189 86.835 168.2 12 Basel 13 0.2414 0.2704 53.360 48.3 11 Man. United 16 0.9422 0.3329 141.507 415.0 9 Otelu i Galati 13 0.1402 0.2970 7.764 18.15 0

Real Mad rid 16 1.5078 0.4148 110.551 542.0 18

Lyon 15 0.9173 0.3394 94.802 152.2 8

Ajax 13 0.4911 0.3211 57.943 97.35 8

Dinam o Zagreb 13 0.2734 0.2972 24.774 44.8 0

Chelsea 16 1.3500 0.3127 122.507 381.0 11

Bayer Leverku ssen 13 0.5609 0.2907 59.403 137.0 10

Valencia 13 0.3030 0.1755 83.551 180.0 8

Genk 13 0.2367 0.2882 12.480 47.9 3

Arsenal 15 0.8089 0.3250 113.507 299.25 11

Marseille 13 0.5882 0.2520 84.802 140.65 10

Olym p iacos 15 0.3067 0.3118 61.420 81.4 9

Boru ssia Dortm u nd 16 0.6031 0.4752 30.403 179.75 4

Ap oel 13 0.2604 0.3221 33.599 14.95 9 Zenit 13 0.3172 0.2421 79.066 155.2 9 Porto 13 0.3976 0.2730 97.835 210.0 8 Shakhtar 13 0.4391 0.4539 83.894 143.45 5 Barcelona 16 1.6711 0.3680 151.551 579.0 16 AC Milan 25 1.2758 0.6483 88.853 266.3 9 Plzen 13 0.2166 0.3445 14.070 163.0 5 Bate Borisov 13 0.1112 0.2403 29.641 17.05 2

Notes: (1) & (2): For the three Italian teams, the annual wages are found in: http://www.xtratime.org/forum/showthread.php?t=261972 ; for all other teams, searching extensively various sport sites, forums and the teams’ official sites; most values for the following teams are uncertain and for the non- Euro teams, estimated with various exchanges rates into €: Trabzonspor, Otelui Galati, Dinamo Zagreb, Genk, Apoel, Plzen, Bate Borisov.

(3): http://kassiesa.home.xs4all.nl/bert/uefa/data/method4/trank2012.html (4): http://www.transfermarkt.co.uk/

(17)

16

References

Arrow , K., et al (1961): Cap ital-labor su bstitu tion and econom ic efficiency, Review of Economics & Statistics, 43, pp. 228-232.

Avru tin, B. M. & P. M. Som m ers (2007): Work incentives and salary d istribu tions in m ajor leagu e baseball, A tlantic Economic Journal, 35, pp. 509-510.

Breu nig, R., et al (2012): Wage d isp ersion and team p erform ance: a theoretical m od el and evid ence from baseball, Discussion Paper N o. 663, Centre for Economic Policy research, The A ustralian N ational University.

Fehr, E. & K. M. Schm id t (1999): A theory of fairness, com p etition, and coop eration, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114, pp. 817-868.

Franck, E. & S. N ü esch (2007): Wage d isp ersion and team p erform ance – An em p irical p anel analysis, W orking Paper N o. 73, Institute for Strategy and Business Economics, University of Z urich.

H irotsu , N . & M. B. Wright (2006): Mod eling tactical changes of form ation in association football as a zero-su m gam e, 2 (2), article 4, Journal of Quantitative A nalysis in Sports, The Berkeley Electronic Press.

Kesenne, S., (2007): Does a w in bonu s help to increase p rofit or w ins in p rofessional team sp orts? W orking Paper, Economics Department, University of A ntwerp.

Lazear, E. P. (1989): Pay equ ality and ind u strial p olitics, Journal of Political Economy, 97, pp. 561-580.

Lazear, E. P. & S. Rosen (1981): Rank-ord er tou rnam ents as op tim u m labor contracts, Journal of Political Economy, 89, pp. 841-964.

Levine, D. I. (1991): Cohesiveness, p rod u ctivity, and w age d ispersion, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 15, pp. 237-255.

Milgrom , P. R. (1988): Em p loym ent contracts. Influ ence activities, and efficient organization d esigns, Journal of Political Economy, 96, pp. 42-60.

Pap ahristod ou lou , C. (2008): An analysis of UEFA Cham p ions Leagu e m atch statistics, International Journal of A pplied Sports Science, 20 (1) pp.67-93.

(18)

17

Pokorny, K. (2004): Pay – bu t d on’t p ay too m u ch: An exp erim ental stu d y on the im p act of incentives, W orking Paper, (available at http :/ / ssrn.com / abstract=614742)

Sim m ons, R. & D. J. Berri (2011): Mixing the p rinces and the p au p ers: Pay and p erform ance in the national basket association , Labour Economics, 18, pp. 381-388. Torgler, B., et al (2008): Looking aw kw ard w hen w inning and foolish w hen losing: Inequ ality aversion and p erform ance in the field , W orking Paper N o 2008-11, Center for Research in Economics, M anagement and the A rts, Basel.

Wisem an, F. & S. Chatterjee (2003): Team payroll and team p erform ance in m ajor leagu e baseball 1985-2002, Economics Bulletin, 1(2), pp. 1-10.

http://www.football-marketing.com/2010/09/07/italian-serie-a-wage-list/ http://www.xtratime.org/forum/showthread.php?t=261972 http://kassiesa.home.xs4all.nl/bert/uefa/data/method4/trank2012.html http://www.transfermarkt.co.uk/ http://www.uefa.com/uefachampionsleague/season=2012/matches/round=200026 3/index.html

References

Related documents

In the anaerobic granulation process monitoring the Equivalent Diameter and Area Percentage values revealed a shift in the aggregates size from the 0.01-0.1 mm to the 0.1-1 mm

} Drive Lock-Out with "Smarts": Prevents the occupant from driving the chair if the tilt and/or recline angle exceed a specified limit, as determined by the therapist9.

Samtliga tekniska parametrar gäller för hela lampan / På grund av den komplicerade tillverkningsprocessen för lysdioder, så är de typiska värden för LED och de tekniska

Produktkod Förpackningsenhet (Styck/Enhet) Förpackningsenhet (Styck/Enhet) Dimensioner (längd x bredd x höjd) Dimensioner (längd x bredd x höjd) Bruttovikt Bruttovikt Volym

Samtliga tekniska parametrar gäller för hela lampan / På grund av den komplicerade tillverkningsprocessen för lysdioder, så är de typiska värden för LED och de tekniska

Innehållsförteckning Sidan Låssystem, elektroniskt 4-6 Nyckelrör B-Lock Flex 7 Nyckelbox B-Lock Combi 8 Nyckelbox B-Lock Multi 9..

• För att undvika skador på tallriken, se till att rätter och behållare lyfts bort från tallrikens kant när du tar ut dem ur ugnen.. För användning av stativet se

Samtliga tekniska parametrar gäller för hela lampan / På grund av den komplicerade tillverkningsprocessen för lysdioder, så är de typiska värden för LED och de tekniska