• No results found

Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption"

Copied!
36
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

http://www.diva-portal.org

Postprint

This is the accepted version of a paper published in Public Integrity. This paper has been peer-reviewed but does not include the final publisher proof-corrections or journal pagination.

Citation for the original published paper (version of record): Andersson, S. (2017)

Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption. Public Integrity, 19(1): 58-76

https://doi.org/10.1080/10999922.2016.1200408

Access to the published version may require subscription. N.B. When citing this work, cite the original published paper.

Permanent link to this version:

(2)

P

Public Integrity

Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption

--Manuscript Draft--Manuscript Number: PUBLICINTEGRITY-D-15-00048R2

Full Title: Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption Article Type: Original Article

Abstract: This article discusses the effects of standard corruption measurement used in comparative research for accuracy in estimating and understanding corruption. Implicitly, these measurements treat corruption as a one-dimensional phenomenon (measured by a single score) that can vary in incidence between countries (or other geographical entities), but not in form. They also tend to equate corruption with bribery. This article argues that the degree to which such one-dimensional and bribery focused measurements constitutes a suitable proxy for corruption differs across countries (i.e. the measurement discrepancy is not random across countries). In particular, these measurements are ill suited to capture corruption in established democracies with highly developed economies, where corruption is expected to centre around gaining access to and influence within strong state institutions rather than bribery. Sweden, a "least corrupt" case, is used to illustrate the effects of relying on such measurements in such setting, and to show that bribery might be a relatively rare event, while undue influence and interest conflicts can be a frequent occurrence.

Author Comments:

Keywords: corruption types; bribery; conflict of interest; corruption measurement; influence markets

(3)

Title:

Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption

Contact details:

Staffan Andersson

Department of Political Science Linnaeus University

351 95 Växjö Sweden

Mail: staffan.andersson@lnu.se

(4)

Beyond Unidimensional Measurement of Corruption

Access to empirical data in the form of country-level corruption rankings and indices that can

be used for large-N analysis is one of the main explanations for the rapid growth of corruption

research over the past twenty years or so. This literature has contributed to knowledge of the

causes and effects of corruption and its relationship with democracy, institutions, trust,

economic development, etc. (e.g. Collier, 2002; Kaufmann, Kraay, & Mastruzzi, 2010;

Lambsdorff, 2007; Mauro, 1995; Stockemer, LaMontagne, & Scruggs, 2013; Tanzi, 1998;

Treisman, 2000; Uslaner, 2005).

However, relying on single number country-level measurements, where a single score is

indicating the overall corruption level for a given country (Johnston, 2010, p. 127), that

became standard for cross-national research on corruption also create some problems. Notable

examples of such measurements are composite corruption indices such as Transparency

International’s (2015b) Corruption Perceptions Index (CPI) and the Control of Corruption variable in the World Bank Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) (Kaufmann, et al.,

2010).

One could point to problems related to their empirical foundations (e.g. Andvig, 2005;

Søreide, 2006), the drawbacks if using perceptions to measure actual levels of corruption (e.g.

Arndt & Oman, 2006; Heywood & Rose, 2014), and the varying congruence of perceptions

and experience based measurements (e.g. Andvig, 2005; Groop, 2013; Miller, Grødeland, &

Koshechkina, 2001; Weber Abramo, 2007). Also, and more related to the purpose of this

article, actual instances of corruption might vary spatially, i.e. subnationally (e.g. Charron,

Lapuente, & Rothstein, 2013) and across government levels and sectors (e.g. Alam, 1995),

Main Document 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(5)

something that is not detected by studies relying on single country-level scores. Linde and

Erlingsson (2013) have for example pointed out the limited ability of country indices to grasp

the nature and extent of corruption in countries with strong local self-government, and where

much of the corrupt activities are expected to take place at the local level. Moreover,

concerning the lack of empirical attention to spatial variation within countries (Bland, 2015,

p. 266) the contribution of Charon et al. (2013) is important as it shows the salience of

sub-national variation of quality of government1 and corruption in Europe, and also how in some

countries it is insignificant (e.g. Sweden) while big in others (Charron, 2013b, pp. 106-107).

Yet, in spite of the merits of this literature identifying these problems (above), the key issue to

be addressed in this article is the effect on the accuracy of corruption measurement, especially

for countries with low-corruption and established democracy, of corruption being treated as a

single-dimension phenomenon. The literature often treats corruption as if it consists of one

thing regardless of where or how it occurs. As noted above, this is not always true of all the

literature. There are insightful comparative contributions that use a broader corruption

concept, and that look at forms, public sector fairness and impartiality, and variation (e.g.

Dahlström & Sundell, 2013; Charron et al., 2013; Linde & Erlingsson, 2013; World Bank,

2013). 2 Yet, as noted by Johnston (2010, p. 129, 2015, p. 282), striving for causal

explanations the tendency in the literature is to emphasize variation in quantity rather than in

form. In fact, the literature still often treats corruption as unidimensional and often as

synonymous to bribery (see also Philp, 2015, p. 19).

In fact, as corruption is multifaceted there are many types of corruption, and the form it takes

varies among different kinds of societies and communities, with particular patterns of

corruption being characteristic of specific societal types (Heidenheimer, 1989; Johnston, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(6)

2005). This is often masked in research that compresses all corruption into one dimension,

both composite measures and measures directly focused on bribery. Employing a

one-dimensional view of corruption therefore has potentially negative implications for the

accuracy of the understanding of corruption both within and across countries, and therefore

also affects how it is dealt with.

Corruption is often equated with bribery, and bribery is certainly a core indicator of

corruption. Theoretically though, there are good reasons to believe that the incidence of

bribery in relation to the incidence of all corruption occurrences, including other corruption

types, can be expected to vary across both countries and sectors within countries. Moreover, it

is argued that it is likely that the expected measurement discrepancy does not vary randomly

across countries. Rather, whether or not bribery is a good proxy for overall corruption in a

country depends upon the type of country/society, and how prominent a role this type of

corruption plays in that particular country/society. In countries placed as “low-corruption

countries” in rankings such as the one by Transparency International, namely established democracies and highly developed market economies, types of corruption other than bribery

can be expected (Johnston, 2005). In these contexts, the standard measurements might

therefore lead to faulty conclusions, thus missing an important piece of the corruption puzzle.

In addition, the types of corruption that predominantly fall under the heading of conflict of

interest are expected to be a frequent and key feature in such least-corrupt countries.3 If

corruption measures ignore this form of the phenomenon, research might fail to identify

corruption, hence draw incorrect conclusions about the magnitude of the problem.

So, as the single score standard measurements of corruption in these low-corruption cases are

expected to generate a significant discrepancy between overall corruption and what is 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(7)

measured, this article argues that this problem is particularly important to discuss in relation

to these countries. One way forward is to increase the available data for various corruption

types. But as changes in governance alter the relationship between public and private actors in

public administration, the way public and private interest is perceived is also affected, and

consequently also the understanding of corruption. Hence, there is a need for qualitative

studies that add nuance to the understanding of corruption, and take into account the various

types of corruption that exist, and the variation that can occur within countries and across

levels and sectors of government. Thus, first in-depth, qualitative case studies should be

conducted. Such studies should aim to capture and analyse the role of conflicts of interest and

how they are treated. Conflicts of interest are of particular importance because of the blurred

boundary between public and private interest (e.g. Hood, 1991; Hood & Dixon, 2015).

Corruption is now as likely to take the form of conflict of interest, abuse of office or

inappropriate use of official information, and lobbying by former public officials, as it is to

appear in the more traditional forms of bribery and embezzlement. Thus, interest conflicts are

a key issue for the understanding of corruption in such states and because, as this article will

show, it is difficult to capture using the standard measurements. Such research should include

a consideration of how conflicts of interest have been affected by the changing relations of

interaction between the public sector and business, as well as how this change has impacted

on how conflicts of interest are manifest and dealt with (e.g. Andersson & Anechiarico, 2015;

Heywood, 2015a; O’Brien, 2003).

The argument is illustrated by the least corrupt case of Sweden4 (e.g. Bull & Newell, 2003;

Charron et al., 2013; Heidenheimer, 1996; Rothstein, 2011). A single case is used to allow an

in-depth exploration of the pattern of corruption and hence a clearer illustration of the effects

of using standard measurements. One would, given the theoretical assumptions made here, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(8)

expect a pattern of corruption in this type of case where conflict of interest is important. But

as the exploration of the Swedish case indicates, this is difficult to capture using the standard

measurements and legal data.

The following section elaborates on why the importance of adopting a nuanced view of

corruption is likely to be particularly well illustrated by focusing on least-corrupt countries in

general and Sweden in particular. The article then uses standard and other indicators to look at

the overall level of corruption, types of corruption, and spatial variation across sectors and

levels of government in Sweden.

Studying Varieties of Corruption in Established Democracies

Johnston (2005, p. 39) has explored how different societies develop different patterns of

corruption. These corruption patterns, or syndromes of corruption, reflect combinations of

political participation and the strength of institutions in society. Most Western industrialised

countries, in particular Northern European ones, come out well in studies using standard

corruption measures. In such settings, i.e. “influence markets”, mature open market economies and strong political institutions, legitimate constitutional frameworks, political

competition, free news media, and strong civil societies help to check abuses, but as they

developed these characteristics, powerful wealth interests were accommodated. Consequently,

the corruption syndrome in these settings could be expected to consist of sophisticated forms

of dealing in access to and influence within strong state institutions, rather than deals and

connections circumventing them and high-level bribery. Influence market corruption is

rendered “invisible” (Johnston, 2005, pp. 42-57). 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(9)

The consensus that emerged during the 1990s treats corruption as almost synonymous with

bribery and as both cause and effect of incomplete, uneven, or ineffective economic

liberalization. Although the focus on bribery might be justified in influence markets, it is only

the tip of the iceberg (Johnston, 2005, p. 6). Moreover, rules are adapted to fit wealth interests

in mature, market-orientated democracies (see also Heidenheimer, 1989, p. 161; Lessig, 2013)

and, as noted above, the public-private divide in public administration are increasingly

blurred. This highlights the importance of examining how countries deal with conflict of

interest situations and their changing nature, i.e. what is regarded as a conflict and how

conflicts are sanctioned.

Conflicts of interest generally involve situations in which officials have an outside interest

that could influence the way he/she carries out his/ her public duties, while corruption

concerns situations in which an official abuses trust or power for illicit gain. But interest

conflicts might not always primarily be understood in terms of individual officials as the

cause of violations; the concept of systemic conflict of interest rather emphasizes how in

many high income countries structural changes to public life and public service (i.e.

privatization and outsourcing of public sector activities and the increase in financialization of

national economies) can lead to conflict of interest. And as these conditions change, the way

public officials pursue their interests will be affected too. There is clearly a strong connection

between the concepts of corruption and conflict of interest. Hence, interest conflicts are a key

issue to consider in corruption discussions in mature democracies. How conflicts of interest

between officials’ private interests and their public duties are dealt with has a direct effect on corruption control (Andersson & Anechiaricho, 2015).

A Further Conceptual Discussion of Corruption

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(10)

This discussion will, given the purpose of the article and the way definitions influence the

understanding of corruption, as a start first derive a broad outlook on corruption, that then

allows the development of an empirically employable typology encompassing various

corruption types. As the main interest is public corruption rather than private, the focus of the

article is on corruption in the public sphere or at the interface between the private and public

spheres, i.e. political corruption (Heywood, 1997, p. 421), and to a democratic context.

Concerning corruption in a democracy, Warren (2015, pp. 48-49) views its normative core as

when institutions and practices that should enable democratic inclusion instead are duplicitly

undermined for the purspose of exclusion. But he also stresses how the meaning of corruption

in practice depends on which institutional sphere (e.g legislative or executive) is concerned

and its norms of inclusion. There is thus not one corruption problem; instead institutions are

susceptible to different kinds of corruption that hurt their specific democratic functions.

So along these lines, this section first defines corruption using a broad behaviour based

definition (cf. Heidenheimer, 1970, p. 4). Next, it allows elaborating a typology with focus on

different types of corrupt behaviour that is needed to be considered in the empirical section.5

Corruption could then be defined as abuse of public power in the interest of illicit gain (cf.

Andersson & Heywood, 2009, p. 748). This definition is applicable to different settings, it is

not restricted to law breaking and it does cover corruption where public power involves

private entities or for purposes other than individual gain (e.g. to benefit political parties).

In societies where norms and roles are relatively settled and tolerance for corruption in

general is low6, substantial grey areas are to be expected regarding what behaviours are

considered to be corrupt. Tolerance will also depend on type of corruption, especially when 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(11)

moving from clear-cut cases of bribery to different forms of nepotism and less crude

manifestations of conflict of interest (Gibbons, 1989; Johnston, 1996).

Naturally, an act that is breaking both legal and moral norms is clearly corrupt, while acts that

are perceived as breaking moral but not legal norms represent a grey zone. Moreover, a

narrow legal definition (as in Sweden, see below) potentially implies a greater distance

between the legal definition, and what is socially and morally considered as corruption.

Consequently, there is not just a distance between legal and moral/ethical understandings of

corruption, but the size of this difference might also vary across countries.

Thus, corrupt practices may not be restricted to what is stipulated by penal laws. In general,

direct forms of corruption (e.g. bribery, embezzlement) are rather easy to grasp, but also

more subtle, less clear-cut forms need to be considered (Willbern, 2001, pp. 118-119) in order

not to exclude precisely those forms of concern, for example conflict of interest situations or

undue influence on policy making (cf. Kaufmann, 2005, p. 82). Sticking to a strictly legal

understanding of corruption might indeed, in some cases, lead us away from practice that

corrupts government (Ghere, 2013, p. 6; Jos, 1993, p. 371; Kaufmann, 2011, pp. 195). Also,

the complexity of deviant practices (e.g. favouritism, improper interference, and interest

conflicts) considered ethically wrong cannot easily be made to fit penal categories and might

not transgress the political order despite causing objections (e.g. Johnston, 2015, p. 277;

Mény, 1996, p. 311; Neshkova & Rosenbaum, 2015, pp. 97-98). The importance of their

inclusion is further exacerbated, given the centrality of impartiality for how actions in public

administration are defined and perceived by the public (Rothstein & Teorell, 2008). 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(12)

So, given the generic understanding of corruption (with focus on public power and illicit

gain), the discussion about different types of corruption, and how legal definitions correspond

to broader social definitions, the concluding typology (cf. Bergh, Erlingsson, Sjölin, &

Öhrvall, 2013, pp. 40-42; Huberts, 2010, p. 148) includes Bribery and also: Favouritism, i.e.

abuse of public authority to favour family, friends or party; Embezzlement and fraud, i.e.

undue private gain from the organization or citizens by misleading others or disregarding

professional responsibilities; and, Conflict of interest. The focus of this typology and the

above discussion is on the type of corrupt behaviour, but the following analysis will also

consider and discuss other factors, such as the spatial distribution of corruption between

sectors and levels of government and actors involved (cf. Andersson 2002, p. 33; Punch,

1985).

Extent, Types, and Variation of Corruption in Sweden

First, looking at country level comparisons by using perceptions-based indicators, Sweden

ranks among the most fortunate countries. In Transparency International Corruption

Perceptions Index, which is often used as a proxy for real levels of corruption (but note

criticism of this e.g. Andvig, 2005; Heywood & Rose, 2014), Sweden has never had a score

below 9 (out of ten) since 2000, and after the introduction of the 0-100 scale not below 88

(Transparency International , 2015b).This has strengthened the impression of Sweden as one

of the least corrupt countries in the world. Other similar measures such as the WGI (control of

corruption) also present a similar view of Sweden (World Bank, 2012). Accordingly, based on

these indicators corruption is a rare phenomenon in Sweden. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(13)

Turning from perceptions to people’s own experiences of corruption, one available indicator

used to measure this concerns experience of bribery in contacts with public authorities.

According to the Global Corruption Barometer, one per cent of respondents in Sweden in

2006 and 2007 responded yes to the question of whether they had paid a bribe in their contact

with a public institution in the last 12 months (Western Europe and EU average was two per

cent in 2006 and five per cent in 2007) (Transparency International, 2006, 2007). Several

other surveys have then reported similar results of less or around one per cent (Bergh et al.,

2013; Charron et al., 2013; European Commission, 2014; Oscarsson, 2010)

Thus, these experience-based data on bribery place Sweden among low-corruption countries,

as do perceptions-based corruption measurements. However, this conclusion might also be a

result of the fact that perception-based measures tend to capture bribes better than other forms

of corruption, therefore indicating the same focus as experience-measures of bribery. Also,

the perceptions-based measures above tend not to pick up official misconduct at the local

level (Linde & Erlingsson, 2013).

In contrast to the above country-level results for bribery, Linde and Erlingsson (2013, pp.

591-592) show that Swedes perceive corruption as rather widespread (also compared to

results for their Nordic counterparts). This finding holds regardless of whether respondents

are asked what per cent of politicians and civil servants they think are involved in corruption

(only 11 and 8 per cent respectively believed them not at all to be involved in corruption), or

if they are asked about the impartiality of civil servants. Regarding the latter, 41 per cent of

respondents thought that the treatment one gets from civil servants definitely depends on

personal contacts. Similarly, the European Commission (2014, p. 6) reported that 44 per cent 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(14)

of respondents in Sweden view corruption as widespread (which still is lower than the EU

average of 74).

So, although large-N country level corruption indices (e.g. CPI and WGI) point to very

limited levels of corruption, there are other data that give a different impression. Next, the

article looks at some data on possible spatial distribution of corruption.

Variation Across Sectors and Levels of Government

Turning to indications of sectorial and level-of-government variation, few people perceive

various spheres of society as corruption-free; rather, responses tend to lie in the middle of the

scale. Respondents (in 2011) rated the extent to which groups of professionals are involved in

any type of corruption (scale from 1 “not at all” to 7 “to a very large degree”) as follows (mean values): politicians 4.0, public servants 4.1 and businesspeople 4.5 (Bauhr & Färdigh,

2012, p. 184; similar results in Bauhr & Oscarsson, 2011, p. 86; Linde & Erlingsson, 2013, p.

591; Transparency International, 2006, p. 23).

In terms of citizens’ perceptions of which institutions are more affected by corruption, results are similar to those found in other EU countries (i.e. political parties, the media and business)

(Table 1), though institutions in general have better scores in Sweden.

TABLE 1 ABOUT HERE

Table 2 also include perceptions about corruption (measured as bribes and favouritism) across

level of government. Corruption is perceived as least common in state institutions (migration 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(15)

board and police), followed by trade unions, and then subnational government (county

councils and municipalities), while most common in business.

TABLE 2 ABOUT HERE

Thus, these perception measures show corruption to vary across sectors and levels of

government and in the public sector, to be most common in municipalities (which have

suffered from many revelations). Interestingly, 92.4 of top politicians and public servants in

municipalities have never experienced offers of money or favours in exchange for preferential

decisions, which still leaves a substantial number with such experience (although this does not

say to which extent these offers were accepted). Moreover, they perceive corruption to vary

within municipalities across activities (with technical and construction sectors at the top)

(Bergh et al., 2013, p. 90).

So far, mainly perception data have been relied on, and to lesser extent experience data. One

way to add to this picture is to examine corruption cases reported to and investigated by legal

authorities. The advantage of such hard data is that it is based on actual cases of corruption;

however, there are drawbacks. In cross-country comparisons, the number of legal cases might

compare the effectiveness of legal authorities in bringing offenders to justice rather than the

incidence of corruption across countries. Within-country comparison (the case here) is

affected by the fact that cases reported to legal authorities might not mirror the true level or

distribution of corruption. Penal data in Sweden are heavily focused on bribes, and the

distribution of bribes across sectors and levels of government might not the same as for the

distribution of other types of corruption. Selection effects are also likely, because some types

of corruption might be easier to hide (Hols Salén & Korsell, 2013), and the propensity to 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(16)

report cases might vary across organisations. Nonetheless, for the purpose of investigating

whether different types of measurements reveal different pictures of corruption, these data are

very useful.

The Swedish National Council for Crime Prevention has looked at all alleged cases of

corruption reported to the Anti-Corruption Unit at the Swedish Prosecution Authority

2003-2011 – a total of 684 investigated cases and 1,248 (reduced below due to certain data being

invalid) alleged offenders (Hols Salén & Korsell, 2013, p. 7). Cases of alleged corruption,

which almost entirely concerned bribery, were rather evenly distributed among state

government (27 per cent), local and regional government (26 per cent), and the private sector

(34 per cent) (Table 3). Those alleged of bribe-giving were mainly from the private sector,

while the vast majority of alleged bribe-takers were from the public sector.

TABLE 3 ABOUT HERE

If these figures are compared with the number of convictions, the relationship between state

government and local and regional government changes significantly. The share of state

government offenders increases, while local and regional government offenders drop to just

10 per cent. So here, local government does not stand out as more corruption prone.

Consequently it is interesting to note that the Swedish Public Employment Act (section 22)

requires state agencies to report for prosecution employees who are reasonably suspected of

offences, including bribery and misuse of office (in cases when the offences are assumed to

result in other sanctions than fines). But these requirements do not apply to county councils

and municipalities, which in general is considered as more vulnerable than national

government (Andersson, 2002; Andersson & Erlingsson, 2012; Bergh et al., 2013; Erlingsson, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(17)

2006; Erlingsson, Bergh, & Sjölin, 2008), thereby implying a risk that cases in these

authorities to a greater extent are handled internally and fewer cases being reported (Falk,

2015, p. 60).

Corruption Types and Variation

Let us now continue with how convictions are distributed according to different types of

corruption cross sectors and levels of government (Table 4). The vast majority concern bribe

offences and only a few concern local government.

TABLE 4 ABOUT HERE

For non-bribery offences the per cent committed by persons working for the state government

is also higher than for local government, although not to the same extent. However, cases are

too few for generalizing. So, let us see whether the same distribution for non-bribery offences

remains if looking at alleged offences rather than just convictions. As the number of offences

is still relatively small, however, even here caution is needed in terms of drawing conclusions.

In Table 5, instances of alleged breach of faith against one’s principal are almost evenly

divided between the public and private sector, in contrast to conviction figures in Table 4,

where no case involved the public sector. Results for misuse of office and fraud are though

quite similar whether looking at convictions or alleged cases.

TABLE 5 ABOUT HERE 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(18)

But what are corruption offences (reported to the Anti-Corruption Unit) concretely about?

The majority of bribe-givers are suspected of trying to get recipients to make or abstain from

particular decisions, to disclose information or to strengthen relations (Hols Salén & Korsell,

2013). Overwhelmingly, cases concern attempts to influence sales and

procurement/purchases (61%), followed by attempts to influence legal processes, inspections

and the issuance of permits (Brå, 2007, p. 52). A common denominator among actors

involved is close ties between public servants and the business sector, especially in local and

regional government (Hols Salén & Korsell, 2013). Hence, conflicts of interest are created.

Many cases concern lower-level positions and simple exchanges. As higher positions were

subject to less monitoring (Hols Salén & Korsell, 2013, p. 68), and sophisticated forms of

dealing in access and influence may take other forms than breaking legal rules, their scarcity

is not unexpected. Moreover, overall cases concern public servants rather than politicians (in

state government 75 and 8 per cent respectively with similar local and regional government

figures) (Hols Salén & Korsell, 2013, p. 52). This could be contrasted by alleged cases in a

national daily where public servants and politicians figured to about the same extent (the latter

naturally having high news value). These cases concerned violation of ethical norms as much

as legal rules and many of them concerned whether public funds had been used for private

matters (Andersson, 2002, pp. 236-37).

Survey 2012 (see Hagevi 2014), provides further information about the frequence of various

corruption types. Citizens were asked to what extent (from “own experience” to “just having

heard of it”) they had knowledge abour whether elected or appointed officials in the public sector, or anyone in contact with the public sector, had offered or been offered money,

expensive gifts, expensive trips, or someone getting a job due to contacts or kin. In general, 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(19)

respondents had less experience of the three bribery situations than the nepotism situation

about getting a job (Andersson & Babajan, 2014).

Dahlström & Sundell (2013) present interesting results on the extent of various instances of

corruption and impartiality in municipalities based on perceptions of politicians, from a

survey of all politicians in Swedish municipalities (Gilljam & Karlsson, 2013).Concerning

corruption, in terms of mean values (scale from 1 Not at all, to 7 To a very large extent), local

politicians perceived bribe-giving in terms of a businessperson offering gifts or services to a

civil servant in procurement, (1.82) and bribe-taking when an employee asking for a bribe for

performing regular public service (1.59), at the lower end of the scale and as less common

than corruption concerning recruitment processes: a civil servant is employed despite not

being the most qualified candidate (3.45) and a former politician being employed in a leading

position in a local government owned company (2.63). Also, in terms of rating of to what

extent various government services handle matters impartially (from 1 very little to 5 very

large), recruitment (3.33) was perceived as least impartial followed by procurements (3.70),

then housing (3.71), building permits (3.85), and environmental permits (3.89) (Dahlström &

Sundell, 2013, p. 9 and appendix)

So, citizens and politicians alike rate non-bribery situations as more common. This is

interesting given that penal sanctions for conflict of interest violations concerning

appointments and procurement in the public sector are weak, despite being areas potentially

vulnerable to corrupt influence and being regarded as serious violations by citizens. It is

known from studies presenting respondents with various types of corruption situations, that

citizens do differentiate in their judgement of various actions, that they associate some actions

as likelier to occur at the local government level and others at national level, and that some 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(20)

situations of favouritism and conflict of interest (e.g. civil servants offering relatives without

proper qualifications a job) are judged clearly as corrupt and almost on par with bribery

(Andersson, 2002, pp. 111-118 and appendix III, IV; Bauhr & Färdigh, 2012; Bauhr &

Oscarsson, 2011).

The Legal Definition of Corruption and Conflict of Interest Issues

In Sweden, the legal definition of what constitutes corruption in the penal code focuses on

bribery (the term corruption is not used). Thus, some activities and behaviours defined as

corruption in the conceptual discussion (above) are not legally so. However, they are often

still illegal but defined as other offences. This is true for cases of corruption that would legally

be classified as, for example, breach of faith committed by an agent against his principal,

misuse of office, fraud or embezzlement.7 Bribery offences concern giving and taking bribes

(Penal Code, chapter 10, section 5a-c), and since 2012 (Regeringens proposition, 2011/12:79,

p.1) trading in influence (Penal Code, chapter 10, section 5d) and negligent financing of

bribery (chapter 10, section 5e), which somewhat widened the penal code definition of

corruption.

The way in which corruption is legally dealt with in Sweden is also illuminated by how the

anti-corruption unit of the Swedish Prosecution Authority deals with corruption; its remit is to

handle cases of corruption laid down in the penal code as well as other cases “closely related to these crimes” (Åklagarmyndigheten, 2012). In practise, “closely related” concerns different aspects of abuses of power that have the potential to affect the population’s confidence in how authorities carry out their responsibilities (Stetler, 2012). But most corrupt acts reported as

misuse of office, fraud and breach of trust are dealt with by Local Public Prosecution Offices 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(21)

and are therefore not part of the Anti Corruption Unit figures (Falk, 2015, p. 17). As shown in

tables 4 and 5, reported alleged offences were limited, and convictions few.

Another indicator of the legal definition of corruption is actions and opinions expressed by

other state authorities. The basic foundation of their stance is, of course, the penal code

definition, but sometimes a state authority manifests an interest in the issue in a broader sense.

For example, the government, when commissioning the Agency for Public Management to

study corruption, stipulated the use of Transparency International’s definition of corruption

(i.e. using a position of power to benefit of oneself or a closely related interest) (Statskontoret,

2012, p. 249).

These observations indicate that over the last fifteen years, what legally constitutes corruption

in Sweden has broadened somewhat, although bribery is still emphasized.

Looking to the legal framework to ensure impartiality and integrity in public administration, a

natural starting point is the principle of professional impartiality of public administration. The

Instrument of Government (chapter 1, article 9) stipulates that “Courts of law, administrative

authorities and others performing public administration functions shall pay regard in their

work to the equality of all before the law and shall observe objectivity and impartiality”.

While the most obvious conflict of interest violations, e.g. accepting bribes and embezzlement

(Willbern, 2001, pp. 118-119), are regulated in the penal code, other, more subtle expressions

of disqualification and incompatible interests are not. Conflict of interest situations

(disqualification) in the public sphere are defined and guided by the Administrative Procedure

Act. It sets out instances that are considered to be conflicts (section 11) and prohibits a civil 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(22)

servant with a conflict of interest from processing a case, and requires him/her to give notice

about a conflict (section 12). Rules in the Riksdag Act (chapter 2, article 11) and the Local

Government Act (chapter 5, article 20; chapter 6, article 24) apply to elected members of

assemblies. Hence, members are not to deal with matters that concern themselves or people

close to them. Moreover, the Public Employment Act (section 7) prohibits extra-occupational

activities that could harm confidence in the impartiality of public officials or the reputation of

the agency. (This rule applies to all levels of government.)

But there are also areas without general regulation. There is no general, civil service code of

conduct. For staff in the public sector, there are rules about conflicts of interest and upholding

objectivity, but no specific disclosure requirements concerning assets and financial interests.

Post-employment work restrictions against high-level public servants moving to other jobs in

the private sector are limited, e.g. a minister can leave cabinet for a job in a lobbying firm.8

Moreover, the existing conflict of interest regulation provides only limited possibilities to

impose penal sanctions for conflict of interest violations involving appointments, sales and

procurement9 in the public sector – all functions which potentially are vulnerable to corrupt

influence. These activities are not considered to be an exercise of public authority, which is a

prerequisite for prosecution under the Criminal Code’s rules on professional misconduct, i.e. misuse of office. In practice, individuals are not punished in such cases unless other articles in

the penal code are violated, e.g. bribe-taking.10 Numerous irregularities can occur in

connection with these activities, e.g. actions that advantage one’s own or another person’s

interests, and yet fall short of being actual bribes (Falk, 2009; Molander, 2009). Hence, this

might disguise some of the problems of corruption, and also help explain the low number of 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(23)

corruption cases concerning these matters and the few convictions for misuse of office (see

Table 5).

Conclusion

Standard corruption measurement implicitly treats corruption as a one-dimensional

phenomenon (measured by a single score) that can vary in incidence between countries or

other geographical entities, but not in form. In practice, they also tend to substitute corruption

for bribery. Empirical accuracy then hinges upon whether or not bribery is a good proxy for

corruption, i.e. that bribery is the dominant and characteristic form of corruption in all

countries, or that, at a minimum, it represents corruption equally well (or poorly) in different

countries. However, because forms of corruption are theoretically expected to vary across

countries (as well as within them), this article argues that the degree to which bribery

constitutes a suitable proxy for corruption differs across countries (i.e. it is more accurate for

some countries than others).

So what do we learn from the Swedish case? Our view of corruption, its forms and variation

does indeed depend on how corruption is defined and measured. Types of corruption other

than bribery are important, yet the standard measurements used in comparative research do

not capture them.

One example of how the estimate of corruption depends on what is measured is citizens’

perception of corruption in the public sector as a substantial problem, despite indicating that

they themselves seldom pay bribes. One interpretation of this could be that respondents are

dishonest about their own behaviour, while media revelations about corruption scandals may 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(24)

lead them to overestimate public sector corruption among politicians and public officials (or

simply being dissatisfied with public service might have an effect) in comparison with

Sweden’s standard low-corruption position. Another plausible interpretation is that bribery indeed is an infrequent phenomenon, but this does not automatically mean that other types of

corruption are equally uncommon. Apparently, citizens understand that corruption is more

than bribery and includes interest conflicts, undue influence and favouritism.

Moreover, legal regulations hardly capture the types of corruption that Swedish citizens

consider to be important. The legal definition of corruption (which, in Sweden, is basically

bribery) influences what type of corruption is exposed and penalised, and therefore also the

assessment of how much corruption there is in various sectors and at different levels of

government.

But as noted in relation to some of the vulnerabilities (procurement, sales and appointments)

pertinent for the Swedish case, criminal sanctions are relatively weak and particularly so for

the forms of corruption that are most expected to occur, e.g. conflicts of interest and undue

influence. This is also likely to have consequences for the number of corruption cases that are

reported.

There are two significant implications of the foregoing discussion:

- Unidimensional definitions and measures of corruption are of limited help in

understanding corruption in a particular country, as they fail to recognise that

corruption varies in form, across sectors, and across levels of government. This can

lead to misinterpretation of the prevalence and nature of corruption in that setting, and

a focus on corruption types/problems that are not the most pressing. This might also 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(25)

have policy implications if measures are adopted that overlook important

vulnerabilities and the corruption that actually exists.

- There is a discrepancy in how well unidimensional measures and definitions capture

corruption across national settings that is not expected to be randomly distributed. This

is because bribery tends to be captured better than other forms of corruption, and the

degree to which bribery can serve as a proxy for overall corruption varies depending

on type of society and the corruption syndrome distinctive of it. In established

democracies with highly developed economy and low corruption, such as Sweden,

where the “influence market” corruption syndrome is a characteristic, their accuracy is particularly poor. In such settings, bribery is more likely only the tip of the corruption

ice berg, and undue influence and conflicts of interest are more frequent occurrences.

After having identified the problems with the use of single-score standard measurements,

particularly with regard to low-corruption countries, the way forward is a multi-dimensional

approach. This involves increasing the set of available quantitative data on various corruption

types and even more so, given the way changes in governance and public administration

affects the public-private boundary and the understanding of corruption, to conduct further

in-depth and largely qualitative case studies (e.g. vulnerability analysis and ethnographic studies

of corruption) that nuance the understanding of corruption. Such studies should aim to capture

and discuss the role of conflicts of interest and how these are treated by the political and the

legal systems. Acknowledgements 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(26)

The author would like to thank Frank Anechiarico, Torbjörn Bergman, Cindy Kite, Emma

Ricknell, Sara Fransson, Tigran Babajan, Mia Falk; and participants at conferences in Bergen

and Växjö for their constructive comments on earlier versions of this article, and Linda Hols

Salén and Lars Korsell for early sharing of data. Thanks also to anonymous reviewers for

constructive comments.This study benefitted from funding from the Swedish Research

Council to the project Trust and corruption in local politics. Many thanks to project colleagues

Andreas Bergh, Gissur Erlingsson, Mats Sjölin, and Richard Öhrvall.

References

Administrative Procedure Act. Förvaltningslagen (SFS 1986:223)

Åklagarmyndigheten (2012). Retrieved from:

http://www.aklagare.se/Sok-aklagare/Nationella-aklagarkammare-/Riksenheten-mot-korruption (Accessed November 12, 2012).

Alam, M. S. (1995). A theory of limits on corruption and some applications. Kyklos 48(3), 419-435.

Alatas, S. H. (1990). Corruption: its nature, causes and functions, Aldershot: Avebury. Andersson, S. (2002). Corruption in Sweden: exploring danger zones and change (PhD diss.),

Umeå: Department of Political Science, Umeå University.

Andersson, S. (2012). Antikorruption: arbetet mot korruption. In S. Andersson, (Ed.),

Motståndskraft, oberoende, integritet: kan det svenska samhället stå emot korruption?

Stockholm: Transparency International Sverige.

Andersson, S., & Anechiarico F. (2015). The political economy of conflicts of interest in an era of public private governance. In P.M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge handbook of political

corruption, Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge.

Andersson, S., & Babajan T. (2014). Korruptionen i det svenska folkstyret: vad säger medborgarna? Surveyjournalen 1(2): 103-121.

Andersson, S., & Erlingsson, G. Ó. (2012). New public management and risks of corruption. In D. Tänzler, K. Maras & A. Giannakopoulos (Eds.), The social construction of

corruption in Europe. Farnham: Ashgate.

Andersson, S., & Heywood, P. M. (2009). The politics of perception: use and abuse of Transparency International’s approach to measuring corruption. Political Studies 57(4), 746-767.

Andvig, J. C. (2005) “A house of straw, sticks or bricks”? Some notes on corruption empirics, NUPI working paper 678.

Arndt, C., & Oman, C. (2006). Uses and abuses of governance indicators. Paris: Development Centre of the OECD.

Bauhr, M., & Färdigh, M. A. (2012). Korruption i Sverige 2011: förekomst och acceptans. In L. Weibull, H. Oscarsson & A. Bergström (Eds.), I framtidens skugga: Fyrtiotvå kapitel

om politik, medier och samhälle. Göteborg: SOM-institutet, Göteborgs universitet.

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(27)

Bauhr, M., & Oscarsson, H. (2011). Svenska folkets syn på korruption. In S. Holmberg, L. Weibull, & H. Oscarsson (Eds.), Lycksalighetens ö: fyrtioen kapitel om politik, medier och

samhälle. Göteborg: SOM-institutet, Göteborgs universitet.

Bergh, A., Erlingsson, G. Ó., Sjölin, M., & Öhrvall, R. (2013). Allmän nytta eller egen

vinning? – en ESO-rapport om korruption på svenska. Rapport till expertgruppen för studier i offentlig ekonomi 2013:2. Stockholm: Regeringskansliet.

Brå (2007). Korruptionens struktur i Sverige. ”Den korrupte upphandlaren” och andra fall om utor, bestickning och maktmissbruk. Rapport 2007:21, Brottsförebyggande rådet.

Bull, M. J., & Newell, J. (2003). Corruption in contemporary politics. Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan.

Charron, N. (2013a). Evaluating EU countries by QoG: national level. In N. Charron, V. Lapuente, & B. Rothstein (Eds.), Quality of government and corruption from a European

perspective: a comparative study of good goverment in EU regions. Northampton: Edward

Elgar.

Charron, N. (2013b). QoG at the sub-national level and the EQI. In N. Charron, V. Lapuente & B. Rothstein (Eds.), Quality of government and corruption from a European

perspective: a comparative study of good goverment in EU regions. Northampton: Edward

Elgar.

Charron, N., Lapuente, V., & Rothstein, B. (2013). Quality of government and corruption

from a European perspective: a comparative study of good goverment in EU regions.

Northampton: Edward Elgar.

Collier, M. W. (2002). Explaining corruption: An institutional choice approach. Crime, Law

and Social Change, 38, 1-32.

Dahlström, C. (2015). Bureaucracy and corruption. In P. M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge

handbook of political corruption. Milton Park, Abingdon, Oxon: Routledge.

Erlingsson, G. Ó. (2006). Organisationsförändringar och ökad kommunal korruption.

Kommunal ekonomi och politik, 3(1), 7-40.

Erlingsson, G. Ó., Bergh, A., & Sjölin, M. (2008). Public corruption in Swedish

municipalities: trouble looming on the horizon. Local Government Studies, 34(5), 595-608. European Commission, (2014). EU anti-corruption report. Report from the Commission to

the Council and the European Parliament. Retrieved from: http://ec.europa.eu/dgs/home-

affairs/e-library/documents/policies/organized-crime-and-human-trafficking/corruption/docs/acr_2014_en.pdf (Accessed February 1, 2015). Falk, A.-M. (2009). Korruption och intressekonflikter: hur hanteras offentliga

intressekonflikter av den svenska lagstiftningen? Retrieved from: http://kau.diva-portal.org/smash/record.jsf?pid=diva2:218446 (Accessed April 21, 2011).

Falk, A.-M. (2015). Offentligt maktmissbruk: Problematik, regelverk, prevention, Master’s

thesis in Law, Örebro universitet. Retrieved from:

http://oru.diva-portal.org/smash/record.jsf?pid=diva2%3A862264&dswid=-5124 (Accessed September 1, 2015).

Ghere, R. K. (2013). Introduction. In H. G. Frederickson & R. K. Ghere (Eds.), Ethics in

public management (2 ed.). Armonk, New York: ME Sharpe.

Gibbons, K. M. (1989). Variations in Attitudes towards Corruption in Canada. In A.

Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, & V. LeVine (Eds.), Political Corruption: A Handbook. New Brunswick: Transaction publishers.

Gilljam, M., & Karlsson, D. (2013). Kommun- och landstingsfullmäktigeundersökningen 2012 (KOLFU 2). Göteborgs universitet: Statsvetenskapliga institutionen och

Förvaltningshögskolan. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(28)

Golden, M. A., & Picci, L. (2005). Proposal for a new measure of corruption, illustrated with Italian data. Economics & Politics, 17(1), 37-75.

Greco (2009). Addendum to the Compliance Report on Sweden, RC-II (2007) 1E,

Addendum, Second Evaluation Round, Group of States Against Corruption, The Council of Europe. Retrieved from:

http://www.coe.int/t/dghl/monitoring/greco/evaluations/round2/GrecoRC2(2007)1_Add_S weden_EN.pdf (Accessed September 1, 2015).

Groop, C. (2013). Accountability and corruption: a study into political institutions as referees

between principals and agents (PhD diss.). Åbo: Åbo akademi University Press.

Hagevi, M. (2014). Survey 2012: Teknisk rapport. Surveyjournalen, 1(1), 59–67. Heidenheimer, A. J. (1970). Political Corruption: readings in comparative analysis.

Basingstoke: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.

Heidenheimer, A. J. (1989). Perspectives on the Perception of Corruption. In A. J.

Heidenheimer, M. Johnston, & V. LeVine (Eds.), Political Corruption: A Handbook. New Brunswick: Transaction publishers.

Heidenheimer, A. J. (1996). The topography of corruption: explorations in a comparative perspective. International Social Science Journal, 48(149), 337-347.

Heywood, P. (1997). Political corruption: Problems and perspectives. Political Studies, 45(3), 417-435.

Heywood, P. M. (2015a). Introduction: scale and focus in the study of corruption. In P. M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of Political Corruption. Milton Park, Abingdon: Routledge.

Heywood, P. M. (2015b). Measuring corruption: perspectives, critiques and limits. In P. M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of Political Corruption. Milton Park, Abingdon: Routledge.

Heywood, P. M., & Rose, J. (2014). “Close but no Cigar”: the measurement of corruption.

Journal of Public Policy, 34(3), 507-529.

Salén, L. H., & Korsell, L. E. (2013). Den anmälda korruptionen i Sverige: struktur,

riskfaktorer och motåtgärder. Stockholm: Brottsförebyggande rådet.

Hood, C. (1991). A public management for all seasons. Public administration, 69(1), 3-19. Hood, C., & Dixon, R. (2015). A government that worked better and cost less? evaluating

three decades of reform and change in UK central government. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Huberts, L. W. J. C. (2010). A Multi approach in corruption research: towards a more

comprehensive multi-level framework to study corruption and its causes. In G. de Graaf, P. von Maravic & P. Wagenaar (Eds.), The good cause. Theoretical perspectives on

corruption. Opladen/Farmington Hills: Barbara Budrich Publishers.

Instrument of Government. Regeringsformen (SFS 1974:152).

Johnston, M. (1986). The political consequences of corruption: a reassessment. Comparative

politics, 18(4), 459-477.

Johnston, M. (1996). The search for definitions: the vitality of politics and the issue of corruption. International Social Science Journal, 48(149), 321-335.

Johnston, M. (2005). Syndromes of corruption: wealth, power, and democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Johnston, M. (2006). Assessing the progress of anti-corruption efforts:“Actionable”

indicators of reform. Presentation at Workshop on Governance and Development, Dhaka,

November 11-12, 2006.

Johnston, M. (2010). Assessing vulnerabilities to corruption: indicators and benchmarks of government performance. Public Integrity, 12(2), 125-142.

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(29)

Johnston, M. (2015). Reflection and reassessment: the emerging agenda of corruption research. In P. M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge Handbook of Political Corruption. Milton Park, Abingdon: Routledge.

Jos, P. H. (1993). Empirical corruption research: Beside the (moral) point? Journal of Public

Administration Research and Theory, 3(3), 359-375.

Kaufmann, D. (2005). Myths and realities of governance and corruption. Retrieved from:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=829244 (Accessed September 1, 2015).

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., & Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Issues. Retrieved from:

http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/reports/2010/9/wgi%20kaufmann/09_wg i_kaufmann.pdf (Accessed August 9, 2013).

Kaufmann, D., & Vicente, P. C. (2011). Legal corruption. Economics & Politics, 23(2), 195-219.

Lambsdorf, J. G. (2007). The Institutional Economics of Corruption and Reform. New York: Cambridge University Press.

Lessig, L. (2012). Institutional Corruptions. Retrieved from: http://ssrn.com/abstract=2233582

(Accessed September 1, 2015).

Linde, J., & Erlingsson, G. Ó. (2013). The eroding effect of corruption on system support in Sweden. Governance, 26(4), 585-603.

Local Government Act. Kommunallagen (SFS 1991:900).

Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth. The quarterly journal of economics, 110(3), 681-712.

Mény, Y. (1996). ‘Fin de siècle’corruption: change, crisis and shifting values. International

Social Science Journal, 48(149), 309-320.

Miller, W. L., Grødeland, Å. B., & Koshechkina, T. Y. (2001). A culture of corruption?

Coping with government in post-communist Europe. Budapest: Central European

University Press.

Molander, P. (2009). Regelverk och praxis i offentlig upphandling. Rapport till

Expertgruppen för studier i offentlig ekonomi 2009:2, Regeringskansliet,

Finansdepartementet. Retrieved from:

http://eso.expertgrupp.se/wp-content/uploads/2013/08/ESO-rapport-nr-2.pdf (Accessed January 1, 2012).

Neshkova, M. I., & Rosenbaum, A. (2013). Advancing good government through fighting corruption. In J. L. Perry & R. K. Christensen (Eds.), Handbook of public administration. San Fransisco: Jossey-Bass.

O’Brien, J. (2003). Conflicts of Interest on Wall Street: Corrupted Actors or System? Paper presented at the 11th IACC, Seoul 25-28 May 2003. Retrieved from:

http://iacconference.org/en/conferences/details/11th_iacc/ (Accessed February 2, 2012). Oscarsson, H. (2010). Mutor och korruption. In S. Holmberg & L. Weibull (Eds.), Nordiskt

ljus. Trettiosju kapitel om politik, medier och samhälle. SOM-rapport nr. 50. Göteborg:

SOM-institutet, Göteborgs universitet. Penal Code. Brottsbalken (SFS 1962:700).

Philp, M. (2015). The definition of political corruption. In P. M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge

Handbook of Political Corruption. Milton Park, Abingdon: Routledge.

Public Employment Act. Lag om offentlig anställning (SFS 1994:20). Public Procurement Act. Lag om offentlig upphandling (SFS 2007:1091). Punch, M. (1985). Conduct unbecoming. London: Tavistock.

Regeringens proposition 2011/12:79. En reformerad mutbrottslagstiftning, Stockholm: Regeringskansliet (2012). Retrieved from:

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(30)

http://www.regeringen.se/contentassets/3a1871e1582d44a79b436259f8f192be/en-reformerad-mutbrottslagstiftning-prop.-20111279 (Accessed June 1, 2012). Riksdag Act. Riksdagsordningen (SFS 1974:53).

Reinikka, R. & Svensson, J. (2003). Survey Techniques to Measure and Explain Corruption,

World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3071. Retrieved from: http://dx.doi.org/10.1596/1813-9450-3071 (Accessed September 5, 2015).

Rothstein, B. (2011). The quality of government: Corruption, social trust, and inequality in

international perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Rothstein, B. (2013). Conceptualizing QoG. In N. Charron, V. Lapuente & B. Rothstein (Eds.), Quality of government and corruption from a European perspective: a comparative

study of good goverment in EU regions. Northampton: Edward Elgar.

Rothstein, B., & Teorell, J. (2008). What is quality of government? A theory of impartial government institutions. Governance, 21(2), 165-190.

Søreide, T. (2006). Is it wrong to rank? A critical assessment of corruption indices, Chr. Michelsen Institute. Retrieved from:

http://www.cmi.no/pdf/?file=publications/2006/wp/wp2006-1.pdf (Accessed September 15, 2015).

Statskontoret (2012). Köpta relationer: om korruption i det kommunala Sverige, 2012:20, Statskontoret. Retrieved from:

http://www.statskontoret.se/upload/Publikationer/2012/201220.pdf (Accessed September 15, 2015).

Stetler, G. 2012. Director of the National Anti-Corruption Unit at the Swedish Prosecution Authority, telephone interview conducted by the author 2012-12-18.

Stockemer, D., LaMontagne, B., & Scruggs, L. (2013). Bribes and ballots: The impact of corruption on voter turnout in democracies. International Political Science Review, 34(1), 74-90.

Tanzi, V. (1998). Corruption around the world: Causes, consequences, scope, and cures. IMF

Staff Papers, 45(4), 559-594.

Torsello, D. (2015). Ethnographic study of corruption. In P. M. Heywood (Ed.), Routledge

Handbook of Political Corruption. Milton Park, Abingdon: Routledge.

Transparency International (2006). Report on the Transparency International Global Corruption Barometer 2006.

TransparencyInternational. (2007). Report on the Transparency International Global Corruption Barometer 2007.

TransparencyInternational (2015a). National integrity system assessments. Retrieved from:

https://www.transparency.org/whatwedo/nis (Accessed July 30, 2015)

TransparencyInternational (2015b). What is the corruption perceptions index? Retrieved from: http://www.transparency.org/cpi2012/in_detail (Accessed July 17, 2015). Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal of public

economics, 76(3), 399-457.

UNDP (2008). A user’s guide to Measuring Corruption. Retrieved from:

http://www.undp.org/content/dam/aplaws/publication/en/publications/democratic-

governance/dg-publications-for-website/a-users-guide-to-measuring-corruption/users_guide_measuring_corruption.pdf (Accessed September 15, 2015). Uslaner, E. M. (2005). Trust and corruption. In J. G. Lambsdorff, M. Taube & M. Schramm

(Eds.), The new institutional economics of corruption. London: Routledge.

Weber Abramo, C. (2007). How Much Do Perceptions of Corruption Really Tell Us?, Economics Discussion Papers 2007-19. Retrieved from: http://www.economics-ejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers (Accessed October 20, 2007).

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

(31)

Willbern, Y. (2001). Types and levels of public morality. In W. M. Bruce (Ed.), Classics of

administrative ethics. Boulder: Westview Press.

World Bank (2012). World Bank (2012). Worldwide Governance Indicators. Retrieved from:

http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.asp (Accessed August 9, 2013).

World Bank (2013). Governance and Public Sector Management, see Diagnostic Surveys and Corruption Country Reports. Retrieved from: http://go.worldbank.org/CW6F0PPM20 (Accessed July 30, 2015).

Notes

1 Conceptually, Rothstein (2013, p. 16) defines quality of government broadly as “having impartial government

institutions for the exercise of public power”. For empirical applications see Charron (2013a, 2013b).

2 There are also alternative indicators without focus on corruption per se, e.g. comparing vulnerability for and

institutional strength to resist corruption and expenditure tracking where money is followed to see how much is siphoned off (e.g. Transparency International, 2015a, Golden & Picci, 2005). To go deeper into the drawbacks and advantages of using data based on perceptions, experience, public opinion, expert views, hard data etc. is outside the scope of this article (for this see e.g. Reinikka & Svensson, 2003; UNDP, 2008; Heywood, 2015b; Torsello, 2015).

3 The European Commission (2014, p. 12) found conflicts of interest in decision-making, allocation of public

funds and public procurement to be common in many EU states.

4 For an extensive overview (in Swedish) of corruption in Sweden, see Bergh, Erlingsson, Sjölin, and Öhrvall

(2013).

5 Concerning the importance of distinguishing between different types for the understanding of corruption (e.g.

Alatas, 1990: 3), it has for example been shown that bureaucratic organisation (e.g. recruitment procedures and wages) affects grand and petty corruption differently (Dahlström, 2015, pp. 111, 114-117).

6 In Sweden 97 per cent judged it as wrong/completely wrong for a public official to ask for a favour or bribe in

exchange for his/her service (Bergh et al., 2013, p. 85).

7 The Swedish Penal Code defines Breach of faith as when someone abuses a position of trust managing

financial matters or matters requiring technical expertise, causing the principal harm (Penal Code, chapter 10, section 5). Misuse of office is when a person who, by action or commission, intentionally or through

carelessness, disregards the duties of his office (chapter 20, section 1). Embezzlement is the disregarding of professional responsibilities connected with the handling of assets belonging to another, for the purpose of obtaining material gain or receiving some advantage (chapter 10, section 1-3). Fraud involves misleading another party to engage in action that is advantageous for the initiator and harmful for the other person (chapter 9, sections 1, 3, 11). One should keep in mind that the legal definition of these offences might not correspond with the definition and typology of corruption developed above, in terms of abusing public power for illicit gain.

8 GRECO (2009, pp. 2-3) has criticized this regulative paucity but Sweden has defended its position stressing the

positive effects of having a flexible labour market allowing movement between the public and private sector. Corruption has traditionally been low on the agenda and the government has also referred to the country’s favourable position on the CPI and paucity of legal cases responding to such international peer review (Andersson, 2012, pp. 99-102).

9 In Sweden 28 per cent (EU average 33) of respondent companies that had taken part in public procurement

thought that corruption had prevented them from winning contracts (European Commission, 2014, p. 25).

10 Public authority is exercised when a public authority is in a position of authority in which it wields

decision-making power on another person’s benefits, rights, obligations, disciplinary punishment or other similar condition (Falk, 2009, p. 29). But appointments, sales and public procurement are regarded as

agreements/contracts between two equal parties, rather than such a situation of power. Concerning punishment, labour laws (above) might imply disciplinary sanctions if regulations such as the Public Employment Act’s requirement to maintain impartiality are violated. The Public Procurement Act gives suppliers the right to appeal contract decisions made by authorities. Authorities may pay damages if found to have acted improperly.

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59

References

Related documents

Corruption can proliferate within an organisation as a virus and needs to be remedied, corruption is a kind of social virus, corruption is a dangerous virus

On the basis of a number of impartiality and corruption related questions, and after checking for respondent perceptions bias, we construct three indices: one bribery

Leaving research on corruption as an obstacle to the political advancement of women aside, there are currently three major lines of research in this area: The first line of

In addition, corruption has dramatic effects on social well-being as it contributes to worse educational attainment, lower levels of health and happiness, worse protection of

The interview question was formulated in the following way: “How widespread do you think corruption such as bribe taking is amongst politicians in… (country)?” The

We  begin  the  analysis  of  the  moral  aspects  of  corruption  in  Sweden  by  looking  at  general  patterns in  the data. 

the spread of corruption, but also regarding the level of acceptance for different types of corrupt behavior. The results point at the difference in the assessment of

Key words: monetary remittance, social remittance, migration, petty corruption, sending countries, bribe payment, bribe solicitation, multilevel model, particularistic