• No results found

Tertiary education and employment : Exploring the relationship between tertiary education, employment and overqualification across the EU

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Tertiary education and employment : Exploring the relationship between tertiary education, employment and overqualification across the EU"

Copied!
60
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

Linköping University | Department of Behavioural Sciences and Learning Master program Adult Learning and Global Change, 60 credits Spring 2019|ISRN-number: LIU-IBL/IMPALGC-A—19/002-SE

Tertiary education and

employment:

– Exploring the relationship between tertiary

education, employment and overqualification

across the EU

Maria Papadopoulou

Supervisor: Dr. Erik Nylander Examiner: Dr. Ronny Högberg

Linköpings universitet SE-581 83 Linköping 013-28 10 00, www.liu.se

(2)

Abstract

The dominant human capital theory-based perspective that education is crucial

for economic success and employment has affected national and regional policies in

education and employment worldwide. The present thesis critically assesses the target

for increased number of tertiary education graduates in the current EU agenda for

growth and employment (Europe 2020 Strategy). This target presumes that

employment is positively related with tertiary education qualifications, and that there

is an increasing demand for highly educated workers in the EU labour markets.

Based on Eurostat data, our findings indicate that (i) more public spending on

tertiary education does not seem to be associated with higher employment rates of

graduates in the EU countries; (ii) in more than half of the EU28 member states,

unemployment rates are not related with increased number of graduates; (iii) in most

of the remaining EU countries, the increase in graduates is associated with higher

graduates’ unemployment rates; (iv) increased number of tertiary education graduates

relates with higher overqualification rates in the majority of the EU countries.

These results accord with previous studies which find that investment in

education alone is inadequate to explain complex socio-economic phenomena, such as

graduates’ employment/unemployment. Moreover, they further support previous

research works, which question the proclaimed increased need for highly educated

workers in the EU labour markets. This, in turn, suggests that common European

policies which target at increasing horizontally the number of graduates may further

deteriorate the existing problem of overqualification in the EU.

Without downplaying the importance of education and skills in employment,

(3)

tertiary education in employment may falsely cultivate the perception that education

per se can be the main solution for unemployment. Thus, it is likely to conceal the

wider socio-economic reasons that influence a person’s ability to find, secure and

advance in his/her job. Last, but not least, this perspective narrows down the role of

tertiary education confining it to economic and employment purposes.

Keywords: human capital theory, Europe 2020 Strategy, tertiary education,

(4)

Acknowledgements

First of all, I would like to express my appreciation to my supervisor, Dr. Erik

Nylander, Senior Lecturer at the University of Linköping, for his valuable guidance

and support throughout the preparation of this thesis.

I would, also, like to thank the University of Linköping for having given me

the opportunity to participate in such an interesting master programme. I would like to

extend my sincere thanks to my tutors from the four participating Universities

(Linköping University, Sweden; University of British Columbia, Canada; University

of Western Cape, South Africa; and Australian Catholic University, Australia), as

well as to my fellow students for the inspiring, international learning environment.

Saving the most important for last, I owe special thanks to my husband Nikos,

and our daughters, Chrysa and Sofia. I would like to let them know that it would have

been impossible for me to complete the master programme and the present thesis

without their love, support, and encouragement. I deeply appreciate that they have

(5)

Contents

1. Introduction……… 1

2. Human Capital Theory……… 4

2.1 Foundations and basic principles………. 5

3. Literature Review……….. 7

3.1 The relationship between education and private labour market benefits……….. 8

3.2 The demand for educated workers in contemporary economies and the overqualification phenomenon……….. 15

4. Aim-Research Questions-Methodology……… 22

4.1 Aim and research questions……….. 23

4.2 Method and Methodology………. 23

4.3 Data……….. 25

5. Findings and Discussion……….. 29

5.1 Public expenditure on tertiary education and employment of graduates………. 29

5.2 Percentage of working age population with tertiary education and graduates’ unemployment and overqualification rates in the labour market……… 33

5.3 Discussion of findings and implications……….. 40

6. Concluding remarks……….. 43

(6)

1

1. Introduction

In the context of global economic competition, big emphasis has been placed

on the crucial role of education and skills in shaping a human capital that can foster

economic growth and competitiveness, as well as peoples’ income and employment

status. This perception, influenced by the principles of human capital theory, has put

education at the forefront of policy agendas of supranational organisations, such as

the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) and the

European Union (EU) (Gillies, 2011). Both organisations stress the role of education

and educational systems in addressing the needs of economy, and in preparing

students for employment in a fluid working environment with a changing demand of

skills (CEDEFOP, 2012; OECD, 2011, 2015).

In the context of its economic strategy, the EU highlights the importance of

investing on education and skills of its human capital in order to: (i) achieve its vision

of becoming a knowledge based economy; (ii) ensure economic growth and global

competitiveness based on a high skill-high wage equilibrium; (iii) foster employment

and social inclusion; and (iv) recover from economic crisis (Andor, 2014). This

strategy calls for a close relationship between education and economy, whereby

educational systems play a decisive role in preparing highly-skilled and flexible

employees in order to better address labour market needs, and resolve employers’

persistent difficulties in finding candidates with the proper skills (Andor, 2014).

The EU policies have further promoted the link between tertiary education and

labour marker, by focusing on the employability of graduates (Prokou, 2008). In this

context, tertiary education is widely perceived as preparation for employment, which,

in turn, has changed the role of tertiary education institutions in Europe, and reduced their autonomy (Prokou, 2008; Sułkowski & Zawadzki, 2016).

(7)

2

Commenting about the crucial role of education in employment, OECD (1998,

p. 54) points out that “those with higher levels of education are more likely to

participate in the labour market, face lower risks of unemployment, and receive on

average higher earnings".

The decisive role of education in employment has been reaffirmed in the

current EU agenda for growth and jobs. One of the eight EU strategic targets for

fostering economic growth, employment and social inclusion in the EU is to raise the

number of tertiary education graduates to at least 40% in the age group of 30-34 by

2020 (Europe 2020 Strategy, 2019); a target which has already been met, or even

exceeded, in 18 EU member states (Eurostat newsrelease, 2019)1.The inclusion of this target in the EU agenda for employment presumes that employment is positively

related with tertiary education qualifications, and that there is an increasing demand

for highly educated workers in the EU labour markets.

Apart from the moral issues related to the economically-oriented perception of

education, the importance set on investing in tertiary education for boosting

employment in 28 member states with diverse economies, labour markets, and

educational systems, poses some additional concerns. First, it is questionable whether

investment in tertiary education, which mainly comes from the EU countries’ public

sector2, relates with increased graduates’ employment in the different EU member states. Second, some EU labour markets may not need additional number of

graduates, since they already experience phenomena of high graduates’

1

According to data published by Eurostat in late April 2019, the percentage of people aged 30-34 with tertiary education in the EU28 increased from 23.6% in 2002 to 40.7% in 2018 (Eurostat newsrelease, 2019).

2Financial investment/spending in tertiary education mainly comes from the public sector in the EU

(8)

3

unemployment and/or graduates’ underemployment3, in the form of unwilling part time employment and/or inadequate employment conditions, such as graduates being

employed in a job that requires less qualifications. As such, an increased number of

graduates might further worsen unemployment rates and/or the type of employment

graduates get, namely increasing the number of graduates who are employed in jobs

that require lower qualifications (overqualification phenomenon).

Based on these considerations, the aim of the present thesis is to assess the EU

target for increasing the number of tertiary education graduates. Specifically, it

empirically explores the homogeneity or heterogeneity in the interconnections

between investment in tertiary education, graduates’ employment and

overqualification rates in an EU cross-country context4 using data from the Eurostat database.

Therefore, we first empirically examine whether (and how) public investment

in tertiary education is associated with graduates’ employment rates in different EU

member states. We, then, examine whether increased numbers of graduates relate with

higher graduates’ unemployment and overqualification rates across the EU member

states. The results are expected to provide useful insights about country-specific

variations or possible general trends at the EU level regarding the interplay between

public investment on tertiary education and employment, as well as between the

number of graduates, graduates’ unemployment and overqualification rates.

3According to the International Labour Organization (ILO), underemployment can be distinguished as

time-related underemployment (such as part-time employment) or underemployment due to inadequate employment situations (such as underutilization of workers’ education and skills or low income jobs). They both “reflect an under-utilization of the worker's capacities (thus well-being)… [and] are defined in relation to an alternative work situation in which the person is willing and available to engage” (ILO, 2012, p. 10).

4The analysis includes 28 EU member states, since at the time of writing, despite Brexit, the United

(9)

4

The structure of our thesis is as follows: First, we present the human capital

theory to better comprehend its influence on the EU target, as well as on the

widespread/common perception about the role of education in employment. We, then,

discuss the wider academic debate about two interrelated issues: the role of education

in a person’s successful participation in the labour market, and the demand for highly

educated workers in the knowledge-based economies. Next, we present the aim,

research questions and empirical method employed in our thesis. Finally, we discuss

and relate our findings to the literature, address their possible implications, and

provide some concluding remarks.

2. Human Capital Theory

As mentioned earlier, the target for an increased number of tertiary education

graduates in the current EU agenda for growth and employmentis part of the wider

EU strategy, which reflects the impact of human capital theory principles on the EU

discourse and policy (Gillies, 2011).

Human capital theory is one of the most influential theories both in academia,

and in policy discourse and practice worldwide. In academia, it has been the basis for

a vast number of theoretical and empirical studies in the fields of economics of

education and labour economics, but also in other social sciences. It has been

primarily applied in the analysis of the relationship between education/learning and

private and social economic outcomes, as well as in other aspects of human

behaviour, such as family, fertility, discrimination, inequality etc. (Eide & Showalter,

2010). The ideas of human capital theory have been, also, highly influential in

policy-discourse and practice in economic and educational issues worldwide, emphasizing

(10)

5

legitimizing high public and private spending on it. Since it has significant

repercussions for the economy, it is not surprising that it has been very influential in

the discourse and policies of supranational organisations, such as the OECD and the

EU. Last, but not least, its ideas have been so pervasive that can be also traced in

widespread beliefs about the crucial role of education in a person’s employment,

earnings and socio-economic inclusion.

In order to better comprehend its influence on the logic behind the EU target

for increased graduates in the EU agenda for growth and employment, we go on by

presenting its foundations and basic principles.

2.1 Foundations and basic principles

The importance of human capital, that is the workers’ embedded productive

capabilities, had been acknowledged long before the late 1950s and early 1960s, when

academics from the University of Chicago started formulating it as a theory. Since

then, a number of scholars have contributed in the theoretical and empirical evolution

of the theory. The most prominent of them are: Jacob Mincer, who focused on the

returns to education in the form of wages; Theodore Shultz, who focused on the role

of education in the increased labour productivity; and Gary Becker who organized all

the relevant work into a coherent framework (Eide & Showalter, 2010). The theory

has evolved into one of the most influential economic theories, and two of its

prominent theorists receivedNobel awards in economics (Ted Schultz in1979 and

Gary Becker in 1992).

Human capital is multifaceted and includes a person’s “knowledge, skills,

(11)

6

16). The initial emphasis of human capital theorists on the quantity of education has

been later enriched with an additional concern about its quality, as measured by the

level of specific skills (Hanushek and Wößmann, 2010; Pritchett, 2001).However, the

quantitative aspect of education, measured by years of schooling or level of

qualifications, still remains focal in both policy and academic literature (i.e. Europe

2020 Strategy, 2019; Psacharopoulos and Patrinos, 2004).

According to Becker (1994), one of the most prominent human capital

theorists, a very distinctive element of the human capital theory is that it applies a

cost-benefit approach in its analysis, similar to the cost-benefit approach applied in

investments in traditional (physical or financial) capital. Moreover, it postulates that

investments in education and training are usually the result of rational decisions based

on calculations between costs and benefits (Becker, 1994). Investments in human

capital mainly refer to costs/expenditure on education and training, which result to a

wide range of private and social economic benefits, such as increased productivity,

economic growth, higher employment prospects and earnings (Becker, 1994). These

benefits are perceived to be in a linear positive relationship with investments in

education and skills, whereas deviations are justified on the basis of economic

fluctuations or difficulties in measuring/quantifying indirect effects of investments in

human capital (Becker, 1994).

According to Mincer (1991), which is also one of the leading human capital

theorists, educated workers are considered to have a number of positive private

benefits in the labour market that include higher wages, bigger employment stability

and higher upward mobility in employment and socio-economic status. As far as the

private benefits, human capital literature has extensively highlighted the positive

(12)

7

The basis for this estimation has been the human capital earnings function, introduced

by Mincer in 1974, according to which earnings through employment are associated

with the years of schooling and labour-market experience (Gunderson and

Oreopoulos, 2010).

Overall, human capital theory places education at the heart of its analytical

framework. According to it, expenditure on education and training results in a wide

range of social and private economic benefits, including higher economic growth for a

country or region, and a wide range of labour market benefits for educated people. In

the following section, we focus on the private labour market benefits, and review the

human capital perspective as well as its critiques about the role of education in

determining peoples’ employment and earnings.

3. Literature Review

As discussed earlier, the EU target for increased tertiary education graduates

by 2020 reaffirms the importance of the role of tertiary education for employment in

the contemporary EU Strategy. The inclusion of a target like this in the EU agenda for

employment presumes that employment is positively related with tertiary education

qualifications, and that there is an increasing demand for highly educated workers in

the EU labour markets. Since both of these presumptions are influenced by the human

capital perspective about the crucial role of education in contemporary

knowledge-based economies, we will now continue by reviewing the academic debate between

the human capital perspective advocates and their critics about these two interrelated

issues. We will first present the debate about role of education in labour market

(13)

8

then turn to the academic debate about the demand for highly educated and skilled

workers in contemporary knowledge-based economies.

3.1 The relationship between education and private labour market benefits

The impact of education on employment has been a matter of considerable

debate. Human capital theory, on the one hand, highlights the crucial positive role of

education and skills on a person’s successful participation in the labour market. On

the other hand, a number of scholars question this approach, and consider the

emphasis on education as inadequate for the explanation of such complex

socio-economic issues. In the following pages, we present this academic debate within a

wider debate about the role of education in a range of labour market benefits, i.e.

earned income, employment and socio-economic inclusion.

As we discussed earlier, human capital theory postulates that investments in

education and training are usually the result of rational decisions based on

calculations between costs and benefits (Becker, 1994). Based on this perception, one

may argue that this principle applies at all levels of decision making, including

individuals, firms and countries. As such, individuals make a decision about investing

on their education and training by calculating the costs against expected benefits, such

as better employment prospects, higher wages, and socio-economic inclusion. A firm

makes a decision about investing on the education and training of its workforce by

calculating the costs against expected benefits, such as higher productivity and

economic competitiveness. A country makes a decision about public spending on

education and training by calculating the costs against expected benefits, such as the

(14)

socio-9

economic inclusion for its population. In the following paragraphs, we focus on the

labour market benefits that derive from investments in education, as presented by

human capital theoretical and empirical studies.

Regarding the role of education for employment, one of the most prominent

human capital theorists, Mincer (1991, p. 2) points out that “educated workers enjoy

at least three basic advantages over less educated workers in the labour market: higher

wages, greater upward mobility in income and occupation, and greater employment

stability”. As such, the application of the cost-benefit analytical framework of human

capital theory means that investment in education and skills results in positive private

labour market benefits for educated people, namely enhanced possibilities to be

employed; employment stability; upward occupational mobility; higher earned

income from employment; and upward socio-economic mobility.

Brewer, Hentschke & Eide (2010, p. 193) stress that human capital theory

cost-benefit approach is indeed affirmed in practice, since “better-educated workers

have more favorable labor-market outcomes [and are] critical for a nation to compete

in an increasingly global economy that rewards knowledge and skills”.

Since the monetary aspects and benefits of education are easy to be quantified

and measured, they have been the prime focus of human capital theory (Becker,

1994). As such, most human capital theory-based studies about labour market benefits

have focused on the examination of the relationship between education and earnings

from employment. Their empirical findings indicate that, regardless of inter-county

variations, investments in education, either by measuring years of schooling or levels

of skills, definitely have a positive impact on wages. As far as the highly positive

impact of additional years of schooling on wages, Psacharopoulos and Patrinos (2004)

(15)

10

additional year of schooling. According to them, the latest analyses reiterate that in

advanced economies investments in education behave similarly to investments in

physical capital (cost-benefit approach), since the returns to both “tend to be equated

at the margin” (Psacharopoulos and Patrinos, 2004, p. 118).

This positive relationship is, also, supported by Gunderson and Oreopoulos

(2010), who found that, despite the rapid expansion of education, educational

attainment still exerts a positive impact on the wages of educated workers. According

to their study, wage differences between highly-educated and low-educated workers

are high in Canada and Europe, while they skyrocket in the USA (Gunderson and

Oreopoulos, 2010).

Hanushek, Schwerdt, Wiederhold, & Woessmann (2015) in a cross-country

analysis provided further evidence about the positive relationship between cognitive

skills and wages. They performed a survey with data from the 2011-2012 OECD

Programme for the International Assessment of Adult Competencies (PIAAC), and

concluded that, although there are considerable variations across countries (from 28%

in the USA to less than 15% in Nordic countries), “higher cognitive skills – measured

across numeracy, literacy, and problem-solving domains - are systematically related

to higher wages in all 23 participating countries” (Hanushek, et al., 2015, p. 123).

These works apply a human capital theory analytical framework, and indicate

that investment in education and skills increase the earnings of educated employees

and thus foster their general labour market benefits, such as successful participation in

the labour market, and upward socio-economic mobility. As discussed above, the

human capital theory posits that investment in education is a rational decision based

on the calculation between costs and benefits. Regarding the labour market benefits,

(16)

11

decisive role in the determination of a person’s successful participation in the labour

market: it enhances the possibilities of educated people to be employed; increases

their earnings from employment; reinforces their job stability; and promotes their

upward career and socio-economic mobility. Thus, the successful participation in the

labour market is primarily explained on the basis of a person’s education and skills,

which is a result of his/her decision to invest in education based on a calculation

between costs and expected benefits, in order to maximize his/her labour market

benefits.

A number of scholars, though, question the overemphasis on the role of

education and skills in the explanation of employment and income-related issues.

They argue that the human capital perspective, due to its overemphasis on education

and personal decision about investment in education, fails to address the wider social,

economic and political factors that influence a person’s successful participation in the

labour market. In the following paragraphs we present theoretical and empirical

studies that question the human capital perspective, and argue for the inclusion of

wider factors in the explanation of phenomena concerning employment and income

distribution.

Commenting on the adequacy of human capital perspective in explaining

socio-economic phenomena, Marginson (2019), argues that the favourable economic

and social conditions in the early years of the theory’s formulation provided

supporting empirical evidence, whereas the current socio-economic context of

growing income inequalities, unemployment, and underemployment question its

analytical validity. The growing income inequality (wage polarization) within the

(17)

12

questions the human capital theory, since higher wages are confined in a small

minority of workers.

Based on his findings about the earned income inequality over time, Piketty

(2014) also questions the learning for earning hypothesis of human capital theory. He

points out that although there has been a big increase in educational attainment

worldwide during the 20th century, this has not increased equality of income from employment, as human capital theorists suggest. According to him, the technological

evolution, along with its emphasis on human capital, has created the illusion that

human capital and talent play greater role in the economy than other forms of capital,

such as the industrial, financial or real-estate capital. This, in turn, has created the

illusion that human capital has fostered greater income equality based on one’s merit.

Empirical evidence, though, indicates that income inequality has increased in the

developed world, since “the top thousandth enjoyed spectacular increases in

purchasing power in 1990–2010, while the average person’s purchasing power

stagnated” (Piketty, 2014, p. 320). He demonstrates that income inequality has

skyrocketed in the USA, as well as in other Anglo-Saxon countries, such as the UK,

Canada and Australia. He warns that in continental Europe and Japan income

inequality has, also, increased significantly and, although lower than in the

Anglo-Saxon counties, the trend seems to be towards the same direction.

These studies indicate that although there has been a big increase in

educational attainment worldwide, this has not resulted in higher equality of income

from employment, as human capital theorists suggest. They rather indicate that

education per se may be inadequate to explain income distribution and inequalities in

(18)

13

criticized by a number of scholars, who argue for the inclusion of wider factors in the

explanation of employment, earned income and socio-economic status.

Commenting on this issue, Tan (2014) argues that human capital theory has

overemphasized the role of individual and the individual choice in making a rational

decision about his/her educational investment in order to maximize his/her personal

benefits. Similarly, Bourdieu (1986) points out that human capital theory puts an

excessive focus on personal ability or talent, whereas it disregards issues concerning

social class, and the role of education in social reproduction. Thus, according to

Gillies (2011, p. 235) “the overarching economic, social, and political system is

essentially absent from any analysis… [which] is indicative of a general approach that

sees market capitalism as an uncomplicated norm, a natural arrangement of affairs

above and beyond human concern”. Set within the same context, Marginson (2019)

claims that under human capital theory two heterogeneous fields, i.e. education and

work are treated as one field, whereas the social factors are not considered on their

own merits, but they are rather examined on the basis of how they may influence

individual behaviors and choices.

Based on his findings about increasing income inequality, Piketty emphasizes

that income distribution is a quite complex phenomenon, which is shaped by the

interplay between economic, political and social factors (Piketty, 2014). Fix (2008),

also, argues that there is a need for alternative explanations regarding the social

causes of differences in income distribution. The need for a thorough examination of

the influence of the wider social factors on employment and income is, also,

addressed by Marginson (2019). With respect to education-employment relationship,

Livingstone (2012, p. 109) suggests that it should be rather analyzed within a

(19)

14

haves and have-nots”. Gillies (2011), argues that investment in education per se is not

adequate for fostering employment, as it is evident in the countries, which although

invest in education and training, they are forced to export their human capital due to

the lack of jobs. Thus, he draws our attention to the importance of the wider economic

conditions in fostering employment.

As far as the influence of human capital perspective onthe discourse about the

successful participation in the labour market, McQuaid & Lindsay (2005) express

their concern that since the mid-90’s there has been an increased tendency to narrowly

focus on the role of individuals’ personal traits, such as education, skills or personal

attributes in a person’s ability to find, secure and advance at work (employability).

They argue that supranational organisations, such as OECD and the EU with their

emphasis on education and skills for employment have overstressed the supply side of

employability, while obscured the influence of wider contextual factors (McQuaid &

Lindsay, 2005). According to them, neither the emphasis on supply nor on demand

side of employability can provide a clear picture of what makes an individual able to

enter the labour market, and advance at his/her job. In contrast, they suggest that there

is a need for a more holistic and realistic approach to employability. This should rely

on the understanding of the “dynamic interaction of individual attributes, personal

circumstances, labour market conditions and other ‘context’ factors”, which include

macroeconomic factors, vacancy characteristics, recruitment and employment policy

factors (McQuaid & Lindsay, 2005, p. 207).

Likewise, Berntson, Sverke, & Marklund (2006), argue that besides the

influence of a person’s education, skills, experience and personal attributes on

employability, the influence of other contextual factors, such as the labour market

(20)

15

employability can be better understood when “both structural and individual

dimensions” are taken into consideration (Berntson et al., 2006, p. 223).

So far, we have presented the debate about the role of education in a person’s

employment and earned income. On the one hand, the human capital perspective

advocates argue that empirical evidence supports that investment in education and

skills has a positive relationship with increased earnings of educated employees, as

well as with wider concomitant labour market benefits, such as employment and

upward socio-economic mobility. On the other hand, a number of scholars, present

contrasting empirical findings, question the human capital perspective and argue for

the examination of wider social, economic and political factors that determine

employment and income distribution. After having reviewed the literature about the

role of education in employment and earned income, we now turn to the debate about

the demand for highly educated and skilled workers in contemporary

knowledge-based economies, since both issues relate with the logic of current EU target for

increased tertiary education graduates.

3.2 The demand for educated workers in contemporary economies and the

overqualification phenomenon

As discussed earlier, the EU target for increased tertiary education graduates

in the EU by 2020 draws our attention to two interrelated presuppositions. The first

one is that employment is positively related with investment in advanced education,

and the second one is that there is an increasing demand for highly educated workers

in the EU labour markets. After having reviewed the controversial literature about the

(21)

16

concerns the demand for educated workers in the contemporary knowledge-based

economies. In the following pages we first review the human capital perspective,

which claims that there is an increasing demand for educated workers in the

contemporary knowledge-based economies, and we then go on by presenting

contradictory approaches that question this perception, and emphasize the surplus of

qualifications (overqualification) in the current labour markets.

It is widely advocated that knowledge-based economies face, on the one hand,

an increasing demand for highly educated and skilled workers (Andor, 2014;

CEDEFOP, 2012; OECD, 2011, 2015), and, on the other hand, a decreasing demand

for low-educated and low-skilled workers (Wang, 2012).As such, education and skills

are considered to play a decisive role in employment, an assertion that, as we have

seen, complies with the principles of human capital theory. The increased demand for

highly educated workers and the widening of wage differences between highly

educated and low educated workersin contemporary knowledge-based economies are

strongly supported by a survey published by Gunderson and Oreopoulos in 2010.

Based on their empirical evidence, they conclude that, despite the big supply of

educated workers due to the rapid expansion of education, the demand for educated

workers in knowledge economies is so high, that it exceeds the supply (Gunderson

and Oreopoulos, 2010). The case of a surplus of educated people in the labour market

is, for human capital theorists, a temporary phenomenon attributed to the fluctuations

in economy, which, after some time will be resolved, and monetary benefits from

education will finally be higher than costs (Becker, 1994). As discussed above, the

human capital perspective argues that contemporary economies increasingly need a

highly educated and skilled workforce, and thus education plays a crucial role in

(22)

17

However, a number of scholars question the human capital theory-based

assumption that there has been an increasing need for advanced educated and skilled

workforce in the contemporary labour markets; consider it as exaggeration; and

provide contrasting evidence on this issue. In the following section, we present this

literature with an emphasis on the overeducation5/overqualification phenomenon in the contemporary labour markets.

With respect to the demand of advanced educated workers in modern

economies, Livingstone (2012) claims that a number of empirical studies, mostly

from the USA and Canada, indicate the absence of a major shift in the labour market.

In contrast, the findings show that despite the dramatic shift in the demand for

upgraded skills between 1940 and 1960, the trend has been stabilized since the 1960s

(Livingstone, 2012). Moreover, he points out that predominant fragmented production

process in the labour market, also, questions the claim for an increasing demand for

highly educated workers in the contemporary labour markets (Livingstone, 2012).

The idea that there has been a paradigm shift in capitalist labour markets

towards higher skills is, also, rejected by Lloyd and Payne (2002) and Wilby (2011),

who consider the proclaimed high need for educated workers as overestimation and

exaggeration. In fact, empirical data indicate that companies in the knowledge

economy era do not need more than 15% of highly skilled staff out of their total

workforce (Wilby, 2011), while in the 2000s “the share of jobs held by middle- and

high-skill workers declined…[whereas] low-skill, low-productivity and low-wage

service occupations have gained ground” (Economist, 2014).

The high demand for educated workers is, also, questioned by Manning

(2004), who suggests that the demand for the least-educated and skilled workers will

5Brown (2003, p. 163) warns that the term overeducation should be used very carefully, since it

conceals a “utilitarian view of education”, that is preparation for the labour market, whereas it dismisses “the value of education and learning as an end in itself”.

(23)

18

continue to grow, unless a major future technological change occurs. He claims that

the orthodoxy between economists that technology has uplifted the level of skills

needed in the labour market has created the impression that there is no demand for

low-skilled workers in the current and future labour markets. Although he

acknowledges that “the average job is more skilled now than it used to be”, he claims

that this orthodoxy has oversimplified the effects of technology in the skills demand

in the labour market (Manning, 2004, p. 30). Based on a research on occupational

changes in the UK and the USA over time, he provides a rather encouraging picture of

the future employment perspectives of the low-skilled workers.

The studies presented thus far question the proclaimed high need for educated

workforce, and provide evidence that there has not been a paradigmatic shift towards

higher education and skills in the contemporary labour markets. Furthermore, some

studies argue that the observed overeducation/overqualification6of a number of highly educated and skilled people, who, although in employment, occupy jobs that require

less education, further questions the increasing demand for educated workers.

Moreover, since their wages are not equivalent to their level of education and

qualifications, this phenomenon can also question the proclaimed positive relationship

between investment in education and labour market benefits. In the following

paragraphs, we present the scholarship that sheds light to the phenomenon of

overeducation/overqualification.

Analysing the phenomenon of overeducation/overqualification, McGuinness

(2006, p. 414-415) points out that it is mainly associated with insufficient demand for

6Both overeducation and overqualification refer to extra education [either in years of schooling

(overeducation) or in qualification level (overqualification)] than that required by the workers’ current job (CEDEFOP, 2010, p. 13). In this section we use the term “overeducation/overqualification” to encompass both situations of extra education, as presented in the relevant literature. In our empirical part, we focus at the level of qualifications (overqualification), since it relates to the EU target for increased number of graduates.

(24)

19

educated people, and the “inflexible labour market, whereby employers are either

unable or unwilling to alter their production processes to fully utilize the skills of their

overeducated workers”. He claims that the phenomenon of

overeducation/overqualification, as evidenced in “worker under-utilization and wage

rates below the marginal product” in a number of labour markets, poses some

questions about the validity of human capital theory (McGuinness, 2006, p. 390). In

contrast to the human capital theory assertion that overeducation/overqualification is a

temporary phenomenon, he indicates that evidence from a considerable number of

surveys suggest that overeducation/overqualification may be a long-term problem.

Moreover, he claims that overeducation/overqualification is not result of a “statistical

artefact generated by either inadequate measurement techniques or a lack of sufficient

controls within the standard wage equation framework”, as it may proposed by human

capital theorists (McGuinness, 2006, p. 388). He warns that the effects of

overeducation/overqualification constitute “an economic reality” (McGuinness, 2006,

p. 387), which may be detrimental and “costly” for individuals, companies and

economy, and therefore should be a matter of serious concern (McGuinness, 2006, p.

387). Following these considerations, he maintains that policies which aim at

increasing the number of university graduates may further deteriorate the problem.

Commenting on whether overeducation/overqualification is a temporary

phenomenon, Tan (2014, p. 430), also, argues that a series of empirical studies have

shown that “overeducation appears to be a substantive and durable phenomenon”, in

contrast to the human capital theory-based assertion that

overeducation/overqualification is a temporary phenomenon, and that education will

eventually provide good employment.

(25)

20

phenomenon of overeducation/overqualification in a number of contemporary labour

markets further questions the proclaimed increasing demand for educated workers, as

well as the proclaimed positive relationship between investment in education and

labour market benefits.

The presentation of the diverse theoretical and empirical studies in the

literature review chapter indicates that the education-employment relationship has

been a matter of high controversy. On the one hand, the adherents of human capital

theory claim that modern economies require advanced educated and skilled workers,

and provide empirical evidence on the positive role of education and skills in

employment, earned income, and socio-economic inclusion (see inter alia Becker,

1994; Gunderson and Oreopoulos, 2010; Hanushek, et al., 2015; Mincer, 1991;

Psacharopoulos and Patrinos, 2004). These empirical works are based on a calculation

between costs and benefits using either the quantitative dimension of education (years

of schooling, level of qualifications) or its qualitative dimension in terms of skills.

The main idea is that investment/expenditure on education and skills (cost) results in

positive outcomes (benefits) in terms of jobs, wages and upward socio-economic

mobility. No matter the wide variations in emphasis, the human capital theory asserts

that it is the personal traits in terms of education, skills, experience, etc. that primarily

determine a person’s ability to find and secure a job, earn money through employment

and move up the socio-economic ladder. Investments in education are considered to

be the result of a rational decision based on the calculation between educational costs

and labour market benefits. Cases of highly-educated people being unemployed or in

positions that do not require this high level of education are dealt as temporary

(26)

21

(Becker, 1994). In summary, according to the human capital theory, modern

economies require a high number of educated workers; investment in education and

skills are in linear positive relationship with labour market benefits; and phenomena

of overqualification are temporary, since educational investments always pay-off at

last in terms of good employment, high earnings and upward socio-economic

mobility.

Since, according to human capital theory, investments in education and skills,

play a decisive role both in labour market benefits, but also in a country’s economic

growth and competitiveness, education has been placed at the forefront of the

international, regional and national agendas. This perception has legitimized

countries’ high public expenditure on education for achieving economic growth, as

well as for fostering employment and socio-economic inclusion for their populations.

Moreover, its ideas about the connection between education and labour market

benefits can be traced in widespread beliefs about the crucial role of education in

employment, earnings and socio-economic inclusion.

Human capital theory critics, on the other hand, question the human capital

theory assumptions about the linear positive relationship between education and a

person’s labour market benefits, as well as the proclaimed increasing demand for

educated workers in the contemporary labour markets (see inter alia Brown and

Tannock, 2009; Gillies, 2011; Livingstone, 2012; Manning 2004; McGuinness, 2006;

Piketty, 2014). They point out that political, social, economic and labour market

factors are absent in the analytical framework of the human capital perspective, which

puts a disproportionate emphasis on education for the explanation of complex

socio-economic phenomena, such as employment, earned income, and socio-socio-economic

(27)

22

worldwide, and the long-lasting phenomena of highly-educated people being

unemployed or overqualified for their jobs in the contemporary labour markets reflect

the limitations of human capital theory in the explanation of employment-related

phenomena.

So far we have presented the diverse scholarship about two interrelated issues:

the education-employment relationship and the demand for advanced educated

workers in contemporary labour markets. We now go back to the EU target for

increased tertiary education graduates in the EU by 2020, and critically assess it

within the empirical part of our thesis. Our aim, research questions and methodology

are presented in the following section.

4. Aim-Research Questions-Methodology

Having reviewed the conflicting approaches in the literature about the

relationship between investment in education and employment benefits, as well as

about the demand for highly educated workers in the contemporary labour markets,

we return to the current EU target for increased number of tertiary education

graduates in the EU agenda for growth and employment. As discussed earlier, this

target presumes that employment is positively related with tertiary education

qualifications, and that there is an increasing demand for highly educated workers in

(28)

23

4.1 Aim and research questions

The aim of the present thesis is to assess this specific EU target by empirically

exploring the interconnections between investment in tertiary education, graduates’

employment and overqualification rates in an EU cross-country context7 using data from the Eurostat database.

The concomitant research questions posed in this thesis concern three closely

related issues across the EU member states: a) whether and how public expenditure on

tertiary education relates with graduates’ employment, b) whether increased numbers

of tertiary education graduates relate to higher graduates’ unemployment rates, and c)

whether increasing the number of tertiary education graduates relates to higher

overqualification rates. This quantitative evidence will provide useful insights about

country-specific variations or possible general EU trends in the associations between

public investment on tertiary education and employment, as well as between the

number of graduates and unemployment and overqualification rates across the EU. As

such, we will be able to draw conclusions on the viability of adopting a pan-European

educational target for increasing employment.

4.2 Method and Methodology

Since our aim is to examine our research questions in an EU cross-country

context, a quantitative research design has been selected. Furthermore, within the

context of the dominant “qualitative research paradigm” (Fejes & Nylander, 2019, p.

128), and the “limited availability of research drawing on secondary data analyses”

(Boeren, 2019, p. 151) in the field of adult education and learning, our quantitative

7The analysis includes 28 EU member states, since at the time of writing, despite Brexit, the United

(29)

24

analysis using data from the Eurostat, may provide an “evidence-base” for policy

debate (Boeren, 2019, p. 152), as far as the relevant issues in the EU sphere are

concerned. We should clarify that this study intends to investigate relationships

between variables (correlations), meaning “searching for evidence that the variation in

one variable coincides with variation in another variable” (Bryman, 2012, p. 339). We

opt for correlations, rather than using regression analysis, as the latter requires the determination of the direction of causality between variables (independent → dependent). The identification of causal effects in the explanation of social

phenomena, nevertheless, is very difficult, highly controversial (Aldridge & Levine,

2001), and beyond the scope of the present thesis8.

Therefore, the statistical analysis of our data is based on correlation

coefficients (Bryman, 2012). A correlation coefficient statistically measures the

degree of relationship between two variables and assumes values in the range from −1 to +1. A correlation coefficient equal to +1 indicates the strongest possible positive

relationship between the variables under investigation (the two variables consistently

vary together, e.g. as one variable increases, the other variable increases by the same

amount). In contrast, a correlation coefficient equal to -1 indicates the strongest

possible negative relationship between the two variables. Finally, a correlation

coefficient equal to 0 indicates the absence of any relationship between the two

variables. We report the correlation coefficients, along with their associated p-values,

to indicate the statistical significance of the correlation coefficients. P-values refer to

the confidence researchers can have in their results (Bryman, 2012). For instance, a

p-value = 0.10, indicates that the correlation coefficient is statistically significant at the

8For an extended critique about the human capital methodological flaws concerning regressions of

interdependent variables in the explanation of complex social phenomena related to education, work and earnings, see Marginson (2019).

(30)

25

10% level. This means that the researcher accepts a level of risk/probability that only

10 in 100 of his/her findings might have emerged by chance. As tools of analysis,

correlation coefficients are simple and easily understood. Yet, correlation coefficients

present certain problems, including the possibility of incorrectly being used to infer

a causal relationship between the variables (Bryman, 2012), which is, as mentioned

earlier, beyond the scope of our thesis. The empirical analysis employed in our thesis

does not claim to be a complex statistical exercise; yet it is suitable for exploring the

theoretical propositions of human capital theory which predicts linear relationships

between (investment in) education and positive labour market outcomes. As such, our

research design is expected to provide useful insights for the issue at hand.

4.3 Data

As mentioned before, our research questions will be explored in a cross

country setting using secondary data from Eurostat Statistics, which provide

high-quality and harmonized data for the EU area. Eurostat is the statistical office of the

European Union, whose “main role is to process and publish comparable statistical

information at European level… [through] a common statistical ‘language' that

embraces concepts, methods, structures and technical standards (Eurostat, 2019a). It

uses a “harmonized methodology” to “consolidate” the data from EU national

authorities and ensure that they are “harmonized” and “comparable” (Eurostat,

2019a). Thus, the Eurostat database is suitable for our investigation, since it covers a

large geographical area (the EU), and its rigorous procedures of collecting data ensure

a high level of data reliability and validity. Moreover, the databases can be accessed

(31)

26

We have selected a time frame from 2008 until 2017, which covers the first

ten years after the 2008 economic crisis and more than half of the implementation

period for Europe 2020 Strategy, which envisages the target for increased number of

tertiary education graduates. Our cross-country context covers all the 28 European

Union Member States.

We focus on the following variables:

Variables:

1. General government expenditure on tertiary education (as a share of GDP)

Our first variable measures government expenditure on tertiary education as a

percentage of Gross Domestic Product (GDP)9. The term tertiary education used in the four first variables refers to the UNESCO’s international educational

classification, as per Eurostat. Eurostat’s data are based on the International Standard

Classification of Education (ISCED), which ensures comparability between the

ISCED 1997, with 7 levels of education, and ISCED 2011 with 9 levels of education

(Eurostat, 2019b). In the currently used classification (ISCED 2011), tertiary

education includes educational levels from 5 to 8. ISCED 5 refers to short-cycle

tertiary education, ISCED 6 to Bachelor’s or equivalent level, ISCED 7 to Master’s or

equivalent level, and ISCED 8 to Doctoral or equivalent level10.

9 Public spending constitutes the biggest part of the general educational funding in the European Union

although significant variations exist among countries and levels of education (Eurydice, 2012).

10We use ISCED 2011 classification for tertiary education, as per Eurostat. Nevertheless, it should be

noted that measurements can be arbitrary, since there are variations in the classification of different programmes among countries, particularly as far as vocational programmes are concerned. For example, in some EU counties, professional and vocationally oriented post-secondary programmes, offered outside of higher education, may fall within ISCED 2011 Level 5 (e.g. Austria, Czech Republic, Greece, Spain, Ireland, Slovakia, Sweden, the United Kingdom) or 6 (Germany, Denmark, Estonia, the Netherlands) (For an extended discussion, see European Commission, 2016). Moreover, it should be, noted, that some vocational or occupational qualifications are not included and classified

(32)

27 2. Employment rates of tertiary education graduates (15-64 years)

Given our focus on tertiary education, we use the variable “employment rates

of tertiary education graduates” to distinguish the tertiary education graduates from

the more general Eurostat term “graduates”, which refers both to graduates from

upper secondary and tertiary levels (Eurostat, 2019c). The age group examined is

15-64 years old.

For Eurostat (2019d), individuals are classified in 3 distinct

categories: employed, unemployed, and economically inactive, applying

the International Labour Organisation (ILO)'s definitions of employment and

unemployment. Employed persons are the persons with minimum age of 15 years

who are in one of the following 2 categories: “(a) persons who during the reference

week worked for at least one hour for pay or profit or family gain, (b) persons who

were not at work during the reference week but had a job or business from which they

were temporarily absent”.

3. Percentage of working age population with tertiary education

This variable refers to the percentage of population with tertiary education (as

a % of the working age population: 15-64 years old) within a country.

4. Unemployment rates of tertiary education graduates in the working age population

according to ISCED levels, but are rather classified by the European Qualification Framework, which applies an outcome-based approach (European Commission, 2016).

(33)

28

This variable refers to the unemployment rates of tertiary education graduates

in the working age population (15-64 years old) within a country. For Eurostat

(2019d), unemployed persons are the persons with minimum age of 15 years who are

not employed according to the definition of employment above; are currently

available for work; and actively seek for work.

5. Overqualification rates (whole economy)

This variable is about overqualification rates in the labour market concerning

the whole economy. Overqualification rates refer to the share (%) of tertiary

education graduates (ISCED11 categories 5 to 8), aged 20-64, working in occupations

for which tertiary education is not required (categories 4 to 9 of the ISCO08

classification) over the total number of employed (tertiary education) graduates. We

acknowledge that this variable might raise some questions about its methodological

validity. Even though it is not yet considered as “methodologically grounded, Eurostat

uses it in its official statistics “as an experimental tool to measure over qualification”,

[because] it gives useful insight and… [because its] intuitive reasoning is

straightforward” (Eurostat, 2019e). Thus, Eurostat with its harmonised methodology,

gives us the opportunity to have comparable data and get useful insights about

overqualification across the EU member states.

In the context of our empirical analysis, we compute the correlation coefficients

(using Excel) for the following variables:

• General government expenditure on tertiary education (as a share of GDP) & Employment rates of tertiary education graduates (15-64 years old).

(34)

29

• Population with tertiary education (15-64 years) (as a % of the total population) & Unemployment rates of tertiary education graduates (15-64

years old).

• Population with tertiary education (15-64 years old) (as a % of the total population) & Overqualification rates (whole economy, aged 20-64).

5. Findings and Discussion

5.1 Public expenditure on tertiary education and employment of graduates

In Table 1 we explore the first research question. As such, we report the

correlation coefficients, along with their associated p-values, between public

expenditure on tertiary education and employment of graduates. The correlation

coefficient for the EU28 is negative (-0.62) and significant at the 10% level. However,

we observe that at the country level the correlation between the two variables is

statistically insignificant in 20 EU countries indicating the absence of any relationship

between public spending on tertiary education and graduates’ employment. In the

remaining EU countries, we observe a statistically significant negative correlation

coefficient in 7 out of 8 instances (Belgium, Czech Republic, Denmark, Lithuania,

Hungary, Poland, and Sweden). This finding suggests that an increase in public

expenditure on tertiary education is negatively associated with graduates’

employment. This, in turn, contradicts the investment-benefit hypothesis proposed by

human capital theory, according to which employment increases with investment in

education. The only country exhibiting a highly significant positive correlation

(35)

p-30

value=0.04), which indicates a positive link (and significant at the 4% level) between

spending on tertiary education and labour market outcomes. This may relate with the

country’s characteristics of the economy and labour market. It may, also relate with

the inclusion of professionally- and vocationally-oriented post-secondary programmes

(36)

31

Table 1. Correlation coefficients between public expenditure on tertiary education

and employment of graduates (years: 2008-2017)

Country Correlation between spending

and employment p-value EU-28 -0.62* 0.06 BE -0.90* 0.00 BG -0.02 0.95 CZ -0.75* 0.01 DK -0.70* 0.02 DE -0.13 0.72 EE -0.44 0.20 IE -0.27 0.44 EL 0.10 0.78 ES 0.17 0.64 FR -0.10 0.79 HR -0.54 0.11 IT -0.51 0.13 CY 0.07 0.85 LV -0.46 0.18 LT -0.73* 0.02 LU -0.06 0.86 HU -0.59* 0.07 MT 0.37 0.29 NL 0.65* 0.04 AT 0.10 0.78 PL -0.69* 0.03 PT -0.15 0.68 RO -0.03 0.93 SI -0.12 0.74 SK 0.16 0.66 FI -0.41 0.24 SE -0.77* 0.01 UK -0.36 0.31

Notes: * indicates statistically significant correlation coefficient at the 10%

significance level.

Overall, this preliminary statistical analysis indicates that more public

spending on tertiary education does not seem to be related with higher employment

rates for graduates. These findings do not support the application of the cost-benefit

framework of human capital theory, according to which investments in education are

(37)

32

expenditures on education) and benefits (such as higher employment prospects for

educated individuals) (Becker, 1994).

From a human capital perspective, these counterintuitive findings may stem

from methodological deficiencies, such as the omitted variables bias and the

simplicity of the statistical measure employed. It may be claimed that the

establishment of a robust relation between the two variables in question requires the

use of additional covariates and the application of more sophisticated statistical

techniques. Although we acknowledge that public spending on tertiary education as a

share of GDP is not the only variable that relates to graduates’ employment, such a

detailed examination lies beyond the scope of the current thesis.

Yet, this preliminary analysis indicates thatinvestment in education seems to

be inadequate for the explanation of complex socio-economic issues, such as

employment. This finding is in line with previous studies, which question the

overemphasis of the human capital theory on education and criticise it for ignoring the

role of wider social, political, and economic factors in determining labour market

participation (Gillies, 2011; Livingstone, 2012; Piketty, 2014; Marginson, 2019).

Moreover, it accords with the view that employment issues should be better

understood as an interplay between individual characteristics (e.g. education, skills or

personal attributes) and wider contextual factors (e.g. labour market and

macroeconomic factors) (Berntson et al., 2006; McQuaid & Lindsay,2005).

We should stress here that our empirical design does not imply that public

spending on tertiary education should be primarily evaluated on the grounds of its

impact on employment rates (as implied by the cost-benefit analytical framework of

human capital theory). In contrast, we believe that public spending on education is

(38)

33

5.2 Percentage of working age population with tertiary education and graduates’

unemployment and overqualification rates in the labour market

Next, we explore the second and third research questions which investigate the

relationship between the percentage of working age population with tertiary education

and graduates’ unemployment and overqualification rates in the labour market. To

this end, Table 2 reports the correlation coefficients between the number of tertiary

education graduates and graduates’ unemployment rates along with their associated

(39)

34

Table 2. Correlation coefficients between percentage of working age population

with tertiary education and graduates’ unemployment rates (years: 2008-2017)

Country Correlation between

percentage of working age population with tertiary education and graduates’ unemployment rates p-value EU-28 0.33 0.36 BE 0.37 0.29 BG 0.07 0.85 CZ -0.20 0.57 DK 0.58* 0.08 DE -0.89* 0.00 EE -0.36 0.30 IE -0.30 0.41 EL 0.81* 0.00 ES 0.47 0.17 FR 0.66* 0.04 HR 0.25 0.49 IT 0.71* 0.02 CY 0.85* 0.00 LV -0.56* 0.09 LT -0.60* 0.07 LU 0.71* 0.02 HU -0.59* 0.07 MT 0.27 0.46 NL 0.52 0.12 AT 0.80* 0.01 PL -0.38 0.27 PT 0.24 0.50 RO -0.06 0.87 SI 0.77* 0.01 SK 0.40 0.26 FI 0.88* 0.00 SE -0.08 0.82 UK -0.37 0.30

Notes: * indicates statistically significant correlation coefficient at the 10%

(40)

35

A number of interesting findings emerge from this exercise. First, we observe

that the correlation coefficients at the country level are statistically insignificant for

15 countries indicating the absence of any relationship between the percentage of

tertiary education graduates within the working age population and graduates’

unemployment rates in more than half of the EU countries. This finding also reflects

to the EU as a whole as the corresponding correlation for EU28 is statistically

insignificant at all conventional levels.

Second, we find statistically significant and positive correlation coefficients

in9 out of 13 instances (Denmark, 0.58; Greece, 0.81; France, 0.66; Italy, 0.71;

Cyprus, 0.85; Luxembourg, 0.71; Austria, 0.80; Slovenia, 0.77; Finland, 0.88). This,

in turn, suggests that in 9 countries the increase in graduates is associated with higher

graduates’ unemployment rates. A possible explanation for this positive association

might be the non-favorable economic and labour market conditions, especially in

Southern European countries which were severely hit by the late 2000seconomic

crisis (Greece, Italy and Cyprus). However, this explanation cannot fully justify the

evidence of a positive correlation between the variables under investigation in

Northern European countries which were much less affected by the crisis.

Furthermore, these results come at odds with Eurostat’s statistical data which show

that educational attainment level plays a crucial role in employment in most European

countries (Eurostat, 2019f). Specifically, these data show that those with a tertiary

level of educational attainment record the highest employment rates and are generally

better protected from the risks of unemployment compared to their peers who enter

the labour market with lower levels of educational attainment. As such, we argue that

our puzzling finding for Northern European countries may stem from the limitations

(41)

36

interpreted with caution.

Third, we observe a statistically significant negative correlation between the

percentage of working age population with tertiary education and graduates’

unemployment rates in four countries, namely Germany (-0.89), Latvia (-0.56),

Lithuania (-0.60) and Hungary (-0.59). Again, the diversity of the countries makes it

difficult to come up with common explanations. In any case, this finding might be

associated with the labour market needs in the specific countries and merits attention

for future research.

Table 3 reports the correlation coefficients between the percentage of working

age population with tertiary education and graduates’ overqualification rates in the

labour market (along with their p-values). We observe that the correlation coefficient

for the EU28 as a whole is positive and highly significant. This outcome is also

reflected at the country level since 20 EU member states exhibit a statistically

significant positive correlation coefficient between the two variables of interest

(Bulgaria, 0.66; Czech Republic, 0.93; Greece, 0.98; Spain, 0.93; France, 0.73;

Croatia, 0.84; Italy, 0.77; Cyprus, 0.75; Lithuania, 0.61; Hungary, 0.92; Malta, 0.96;

Netherlands, 0.70; Austria, 0.98; Poland, 0.90; Romania, 0.95; Slovenia, 0.98;

Slovakia, 0.96; Finland, 0.62; Sweden, 0.82; and the United Kingdom, 0.91).This

finding indicates that when the percentage of graduates in the working age population

increases, more graduates are employed in non-graduate posts in the majority of the

EU countries. This, in turn, suggests that common European policies which target at

increasing horizontally the number of graduates may further deteriorate the existing

problem of overqualification in the EU. This is in line with the studies that claim that

overqualification is not a temporary phenomenon, and therefore it should be a matter

References

Related documents

“University Pedagogy in Greece: findings of empirical research”. The participants then participated in an open discussion based on the questions they had asked before and also

΢χγρξνλα Πεξηβάιινληα Μάζεζεο». Πξνθεηκέλνπ λα επηηεπρζεί ελεξγεηηθή-βησκαηηθή εκπινθή φισλ ησλ ζπκκεηερφλησλ, αθνινπζήζεθε δηαδηθαζία πνπ έρεη ζηνηρεία ελφο

The study discusses how regional characteristics, education, and demographic factors are most often cited as influencing mobility propensity and destination after

This topic is important for educational research because higher education institutions are expected to attract and retain tertiary educated individuals in their

For an immigrant from Europe, the education effect is 0.46 percentage points (one year increases the probability of being employed by 0.46 percentage points), while the effect for

Student centred methods of learning; border pedagogy; action research; field archaeology; dissemination of methods; improvement of learning environment; international discourse

There are differences between the deaf and a general reference population concerning level of educational attainment, position on the labour market and sources of revenue

The Credit Accumulation and Modular Scheme [CAMS] (Rwanda NCHE, 2007d) requires that all public tertiary learning institutions establish provision for