• No results found

On estimation in econometric systems in the presence of time-varying parameters

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "On estimation in econometric systems in the presence of time-varying parameters"

Copied!
30
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

ON ESTIMATION IN ECONOMETRIC SYSTEMS IN THE PRESENCE OF TIME-VARYING PARAMETERS

by Kurt Brännas

AKADEMISK AVHANDLING

som med tillstånd av rektorsämbetet vid Umeå universitet för erhållande av filosofie doktorsexamen framlägges till offentlig granskning i Hörsal B, Samhällsvetarhuset, fredagen den 24 oktober 1980 kl 10.15.

(2)

achievement of correct structural specification in econometric modelling it is then important to allow for parameters that are time-varying, and to apply estimation techniques suitably designed for inference in such models. One realistic model assumption for such parameter variability is the Markovian model, and Kaiman filtering is then assumed to be a conve­ nient estimator. In the thesis several aspects of using Kaiman filtering approaches to estimation in that framework are considered. The application of the Kaiman filter to estimation in econometric models is straightfor­ ward if a set of basic assumptions are satisfied, and if necessary initial specifications can be accurately made. Typically, however, these require­ ments can generally not be perfectly met. It is therefore of great impor­ tance to know the consequences of deviations from the basic assumptions and correct initial specifications for inference, in particular for the small sample situations typical in econometrics. If the consequences are severe it is essential to develop techniques to cope with such aspects.

For estimation in interdependent systems a two stage Kaiman filter is pro­ posed and evaluated, theoretically, as well as by a small sample Monte Carlo study, and empirically. The estimator is approximative, but with promising small sample properties. Only if t he transition matrix of the parameter model and an initial parameter vector are misspecified, the per­ formance deteriorates. Furthermore, the approach provides useful infor­ mation about structural properties, and forms a basis for good short term forecasting.

In a reduced form fraaework most of t he basic assumptions of the traditio­ nal Kaiman filter are relaxed, and the implications are studied. The case of stochastic regressors is, under reasonable additional assumptions, shown to result in an estimator structurally similar to that due to the basic as­ sumptions. The robustness properties are such that in particular the transi­ tion matrix and th e initial parameter vector should be carefully estimated. An estimator for the joint estimation of the transition matrix, the para­ meter vector and t he model residual variance is suggested and utilized to study the consequences of a misspecified parameter model. By estimating th transitions the parameter estimates are seen to be robust in this respect.

(3)
(4)

research program "Econometric Modelling and Control11, at the Depart­ ment of Statistics, University of Umeå.

In submitting the thesis it is my greate pleasure to acknowledge docent Anders Westlund and professor Uno Zackrisson for stimulating supervision in the course of the work. Fruitful comments and sug­ gestions on various parts of the thesis have also been obtained in particular from Göran Arnoldsson, Anders Baudin, Olle Carlsson, Jan Eklöf, Hans Nyquist and Hans Stenlund, all with the Department of Statistics.

The thesis and various manuscript versions have been patiently typed by Åsa Ågren, Maj-Britt Backlund and Berith Melander.

The financial support of the Swedish Research Council for the Humanities and the Social Sciences is gratefully acknowledged.

(5)

1979-5. To appear in Charatsis, E.G. (Ed) Selected papers on con­ temporary econometric problems. North-Holland. Amsterdam. (1981)

[B] On the estimation of time-varying parameters for forecasting and control. Statistical Research Report 1980-10.

[C] On Kaiman filtering in econometric systems. Statistical Research Report 1978-8 (Revised August 1980).

[D] Joint estimation of parameters and their rate of change in varying parameter regression. Statistical Research Report 1980-6.

(6)

1. Introduction

The formation of economic policy is a complex process in which many individuals are involved, and in which their intuitive and qualitative information is mixed with results from applied quantitative analysis. At many levels of decision making in society the usefulness of econo­ metric models is now fully recognized, and models form basic devices in policy formation processes, e.g. Ball (1978).

The primary uses of the econometric models in such a process are three­ fold, e.g. Zackrisson (1977) and Intriligator (1978). Firstly, in es­ tablishing knowledge of the current and historical periods structural analyses by econometric models play an important role. In this stage the acquirement of knowledge of causes and effects, adjustment proces­ ses, etc. are key factors. Secondly, in the offensive stage of preparing future economic policy, the assessment of likely future developments of factors both within and outside the control of the decision makers is important. The forecasting of outside factors largely affects the fore­ casting of the future activities to be planned and is hence very impor­ tant. Thirdly, in the choice between alternative policies and/or in their preparation, policy evaluation techniques based on econometric models can be most rewarding.

Generally in econometric analysis the data used are time series, and the statistical techniques employed to estimate the econometric model assume that unknown parameters are constant over time. This assumption, like some other assumptions underlying econometric model buildning must, how­ ever, be regarded as approximations to reality. In fact, numerous rea­ sons have been provided to demonstrate that the parameters of many macroeconometrie models should be regarded as time-varying, e.g. Cooley (1971) and Rosenberg (1973a). The question then arises whether devia­

tions from the traditional constant parameter assumption severely affect inferences to be drawn on the basis of the conventionally estimated mo­ del. It appears as if the consequences for inference may be severe (e.g. Cooley, 1971 and Cargill and Meyer, 1978), and this has resulted in im­ portant research into estimation techniques for time^varying parameters.

(7)

Only recently, however, the first approaches to structural form esti­ mation of time-varying parameters have been presented, cf. Aagaard-Svendsen (1979) and the reports underlying the thesis summary.

The major purposes of this summary are to indicate why the constant parameter assumption is not always a reasonable one, and to summarize the results of the underlying reports with respect to estimation in econometric systems, when the parameters are time-varying.

The plan of the summary is as follows. Section 2 deals with time-vary-ing parameters, givtime-vary-ing reasons for that based on economic theory and data, as well as indicating some of the consequences for empirical use. Further, a brief survey of approaches to estimation of time-varying pa­ rameters is provided. In section 3 the reports of the thesis are summa­ rized. The merits and drawbacks of the developed approaches are indica­ ted. The final section points at areas where further research is needed, with special stress given to the question of empirical applicability.

2. Time-varying parameters

2.1 Sources of parameter variation

A number of reasons has been given for the parameters of econometric models to be time-varying rather than constant over time. The reasons relate to the two basic components of the econometric problem, i.e. to the theory and the data, and to their conciliation.

A complete review of the economic theoretical reasons is outside the scope of this thesis, and only two reasons for time-varying parameters will be mentioned. It has e.g. long been wellknown that the relation­ ship between quantity and price in a free market is a nonconstant one -the relation switches between a demand and a supply regime. The fur-ther development of this theme has led into what is sometimes called disequi­ librium econometrics (e.g. Bowden, 1978), In the presence of rational expectations it has been argued (Lucas, 1976) that policy making brings

(8)

about an altering structure of the econometric model. The variation in parameters is then dependent on changes in the agents* behaviour. The consequences for estimation have been thoroughly studied by e.g. Wallis (1980) and Wall (1980).

As to reasons for time-varying parameters in data, distinction must be made between reasons in the process of obtaining data from the real world and the real world itself. The gathering of data is based on some conception of the phenomena of interest. As knowledge changes by a changing conception of the real world and/or as an implication of col­ lected data, altered demands may be placed on the data (Morgenstern, 1963 ch. 5). Examples of such alterations are changes in the timing and coverage of variables. In the official production of econoodc statis­ tics such changes are usually clearly stated and th e time series ad­ justed according to the new definitions or measurement procedures. In cases where no such adjustments are performed or where the quality of adjustment is in doubt it is obvious that the relationship between va­ riables is a changing one. In time series covering longer periods of time several redefinitions may have occurred.

In the real world such things as the composition of the population and the institutional setup brings about structural changes. Time invariant parameters, thus, can be regarded as as approximation which is better the shorter is the studied period.

In the actual model specification, i.e. when theory and data are com­ bined, several new problems arise, which may imply time-variation in parameters. A model is a simplified representation of reality and as such all causes to a certain variable can not possibly be included. If then an excluded variable behaves in a nonstationary manner the inter­ cept of the model will be time-varying. If further the excluded vari­ able is correlated with an independent variable the parameter of that variable will be time-varying as well.

Other sources to time-varying parameters are the exclusion of nonli­ near variables which are linearly included, or the replacement of

(9)

nonlinear variables by linear ones, Cooley (1971)• Further, the use of proxy variables in a constant parameter relationship implies time-varying parameters when the correlation between the proxy and the true variable is ncmcoastant, Cooley (1971).

Usually, however, the modeller can never a priori be completely cer­ tain about the prevalance of time-variation in the parameters, or structural changes. For this reason a number of tests for structural change has been proposed. A complete description of these is outside the scope of the thesis, and suffice it to mention only some of the more important oms.

The Chow test (Chow, 1960) assumes a split of the sample into two parts and tests for an abrupt change. A corresponding test has been suggested by Quandt (1960). To test for gradual structural change Brown et al. (1975) proposed several tests based on recursive residuals. An alter­

native to these tests with better power properties is suggested by Garbade (1977). Applications of some of the tests are given in Hackl and Katzenbe i sser (1978).

2.2 Consequences of ignoring parameter variation

Once it has been established that there are reasons to suspect time-variation in parameters in many econometric models, one naturally poses the question of whether the conventional estimation techniques still can be properly applied.

It should here be pointed out that general statements of the conse­ quences of ignoring time-varying parameters naturally are highly de­ pendent on the type and the strength of parameter variation. In the following, the shortcomings of conventional least squares methods are briefly summarized for cases where in fact the parameters are contin-ously time-varying.

(10)

Most of the works reported on this subject are concerned with single equations or reduced forms, and only some limited experience for struc­ tural forms is available. Cooley (1971), in a single relation frame­ work, demonstrates that in general the ordinary least squares (OLS) es­ timator is biased as is the residual variance estimator; see also Ro­ senberg (1973a). By relating the time-varying parameters to each other through a Markovian model, Freebairn (1978) shows that a recursive OLS estimator has the ability of tracking a varying parameter path but more slowly than a time-varying parameter estimator. By utilizing the ap­ proach of Sant (1977), it is possible to show that OLS is an unbiased and consistent estimator of the mean of the parameter process, and that it is inefficient relative to an estimator taking the time-variation into account. This statement is, however, only valid for the special case when the Markovian model simplifies to a random walk model. In considering the consequences for forecasting Coóley (1971) demon­ strates by Monte Carlo studies that time-varying parameter estimators give better short term forecasts than OLS. The same conclusions for empirical models are noted by Cooley (1971, 1975), and McWhorter et al. (1977).

As to structural form estimation only some limited experience is avai­ lable, and then mainly from comparing single equation time-varying parameter estimators with e.g. two stage least squares (2SLS). Brännäs and Westlund (1980b) compare a two stage time-varying parameter esti­ mator analytically with 2SLS and versions of generalized least squares (GLS). In a small sample Monte Carlo study it is observed that OLS and 2SLS perform slightly worse when the parameters obey a random walk mo­ del, and that OLS and 2SLS are more badly off when the transitions in the parameter model are different from unity. In forecasting exercises Cooley (1975) and Baudin and Westlund (1980) note improvements in short-term forecasting accuracy over OLS and 2SLS, respectively, when using single equation time-varying parameter estimators. The same is noted in Brännas (1980b) in comparing 2SLS with both one and two stage Kai­ man estimators. In forecasting several steps ahead 2SLS is generally better (Brännäs, 1980b and McWhorter et al., 1977).

(11)

2.3 A brief survey óf approaches to estimation of time-varying parameters

Since the causes of parameter variations are of a number of different types, it is not surprising to find that many approaches to modelling and estimation have been proposed. À first and rather rough division of approaches is into methods dealing with only a limited number of changes in parameter values and methods allowing for many changes.

In the first group, which are natural correspondents to changes in va­ riable definitions, strikes, wars, etc., one finds some of the by now most wellknown methods. An early approach is the use of dummy variables. The effect of using such variables is that the intercept is allowed to vary, and that the times of variation are assumed a priori known. This approach is now standard in most econometric textbooks, in part because OLS is still an appropriate estimator.

When the slope parameters are allowed to vary over time a small number of times, there is a choice between switching regression and its comple­ ments, segmented and spline regressions. Quandt (1958) introduced switch­ ing regressions for the case of a deterministic switching point. A more general approach, suggested by Goldfeld and Quandt (1972), is to allow the switches to depend on other variables but still in a deterministic fashion. Stochastic alternatives are discussed by e.g. Ouandt (1972). Usually the estimation is based on the likelihood function (cf. Goldfeld and Quandt, 1973 and Bowden, 1978); for a Bayesian alternative, see Ferreira (1975). The actual estimation in cases with unknown switching points is computationally troublesome and to obtain well-behaved likeli­ hood functions, further information has usually to be incorporated.

Segmented and spline regressions can be regarded as special cases of switching regression where various continuity restrictions are imposed in the switching points. The switches are then continous and smooth. The additional restrictions are of ten reasonable and they result in more well-behaved likelihood functions. For a survey of these approaches and some applications, see e.g. Poirier (1976).

(12)

In the second major group of time-varying parameter estimators the parameters are typically assumed to take on an infinite number of va­ lues and in a random manner. A motivation behind this group is that the modeller believes in a changing structure but does not know much about turning points, nor the size and the type of change. The esti­ mators in this group can be distinquished by the amount of structure that is imposed on the sequence of parameter values.

Models that are not assumed to have a dependent sequence of parameter values are usually called random coefficient regressions. This is the standard setting for the regression problem as posed by the Bayesians, e.g. Zellner (1971). In fact, much of the work in the area has Baye-sian origins, with the sampling theory results obtained as the special case of diffuse prior densities. In recent years great influence ori­ ginates from the works of Swamy, e.g. Swamy (1971). For bibliographies, see Johnson (1977, 1980), and for a survey Johnson (1978).

Presently, it seems that the most active area of research is into models With parameters that are random and correlated over time. The present thesis is an example of this. Most of the works has either followed an orthodox approach of extending GLS (e.g. Cooley, 1971 and Rosenberg, 1973b), or a filtering approach originating in Kaimans work (Kaiman, 1960) in engineering. Only recently, it was formally shown that the two approaches coincide in certain instances, Sant (1977).

Cooley (1971) introduced a model and an estimator that logically cor­ responds to the practice of adaptive forecasting. The parameter va^ riation is assumed to be governed by a permanent and a transitory com­ ponent, respectivély, i.e.

* et + ut 3P = ßP + v

pt t-1 t P

(13)

respectively. By substitution of the parameter model into the gene­ ral linear model it is found that the new residuals are heteroscedastic and dependent on unknown covariances for ut and vt'. These are assumed to be given by 2 Cov u. = (1-y) t a E u 2 Cov v. = Y 0 E t v

By forming the likelihood function, under normality assumptions, the

2

unknowns y, a and ß are estimated, with the elements of E and E t

9 u v

assumed a priori known. The approach has been analytically studied by e.g. Cooley (1971) and Cooley and Prescott (1976) and its perfor­ mance in forecasting by e.g. Cooley (19-71, 1975).

An alternative to the Cooley-approach is the varying parameter reg­ ression approach in which the parameters are assumed to follow the first order system

ßt"Vt-i + vt

Combining this with the general linear model results in a system of the same appearence as the system utilized by Kaiman (1960) in deri­ ving filtering equations for ßt. A survey of the applicability of the Kaiman filter in econometrics is given in Äthans (1974). The further treatise of the Kaiman filter is postponed to the next section, as it forms the core of the thesis and requires special attention.

An alternative approach to the Kaiman filter is the one which is based on substitution of the parameter model into the structural relation. Rosenberg (1973a,b) develops and evaluates estimators for this ap­ proach. By entering all the unknowns into the estimation problem the approach, however, runs into severe numerical problems, that by the corresponding filtering approach are significantly reduced; e.g. Brän­ nas (1980a).

(14)

3. The Kalman approach to estimation of stochastic and time-varying parameters

3•1 General background

The Kaiman filter (Kaiman, 1960) was originally introduced as a com­ putationally attractive method for filtering problems related to stochastic difference (and differential) equations. Such equations can be written in the alternative representation of the state space form through a realization; for economic expositions, see e.g. Pres­ ton and Wall (1973), and Aoki (1976).

The Markovian parameter model

(3.1) 3t = At ßt_x + vt

in combination with the linear model

(3.2) yt = xt et + et

takes the form of a state space representation, and hence the Kaiman approach is readily applicable. In systems theory (3.1) is called the system equation and (3.2) the measurement equation. Though (3.1) here represents a model for parameter variation, the approach both can and has been successfully used for other purposes in econometrics as well (e.g. Chow, 1975 and Wall, 1980). In the case of stochastic and time-varying parameters (3.1) is e.g. easily extended to incorporate ex­ planatory variables (e.g. Belsléy, 1973 and Swamy and Tinsley, 1980).

The focus for the estimation is the parameter (state) vector ßt, which is stochastic and time-varying. In sampling theory vocubulary the prob­ lem would then be described as one of prediction. The concept filtering is here used when, in the estimation of there is information on y and X up through time t. If the available information covers a shorter period than t, it is a prediction problem, and if the amount of infor­ mation covers a period longer than t, a smoothing problem.

(15)

(3.3) Y = XAß„+G-XBV N

Sant (1977) showed formally that the GLS estimator can be written in a form equivalent to the Kaiman filter, when the transition matrix equals I. The GLS (or the likelihood estimator) is the special case of a Bayes estimator where the prior density is diffuse. The estima­ tion of 3q has been studied by Sarris (1973) in a Bayesian framework, and by Cooper (1973) using the tools of mixed estimation.

Several alternative derivations of the Kaiman filter have been pro­ vided. Kaiman (1960) used the theory of orthogonal projections, while other researchers have devised derivations based on likelihood, Baye­ sian, and least squares arguments; for a review, see e.g. Jazwinski (1970). Disregarding which approach is chosen, the density of is

estimated by its first and second order conditional moments 3t|t = E(0tlyi»-v-»yt> and Et|t= E(ßt"ßt|t)(ßt~ßt|t)lyl,•,•'yt)• For the model (3.1), and under the assumptions given below, the fil­

tering equations are given as (e.g. Jazwinski, 1970)

(3.4) ec|t-1 At 6t-l|t-l (3.5) + q (3.6) Kc = Ut £t i+ « (3-7) St|t = !:t|t-l-Kt*tEtlt-l -1 (3.8) 8t|t * ßt|t-l + Kt(yt " Vtlt-l*

(16)

(i) xt is a matrix of fixed exogenous variables (ii) the residual vectors e and v satisfy

Ev^ = 0; Ee. = 0; Evv1 = Q; Ee e1 = & R; Ev ef = 0 t 9 t 9 t s ts t s ts 9 t s where ts is the Kronecker delta. Q and R are assumed to

H be a priori known

(iii) the transition matrices A^, t=l,2,...,N are a priori known (iv) the initial parameter vector 3q|q is a priori known, as is

the associated covariance matrix ^q|q*

Clearly, these assumptions make an application of the filtering equa­ tions primarily suitable for reduced forms (fixed xt), and further in particular for situations where previous experience exists (known co-variances, etc-)«

At a theoretical level the present thesis can be regarded as a step towards relaxing these assumptions in the case of reduced as well as structural forms. The efforts put into the work originates from the desire of making the filtering approach a realistic complement to the standard econometric techniques, designed for time-varying parameter problems.

In the case of reduced forms, assumption (i) is relaxed in Brännas (1978), and assumption (iii) and part of (ii) in Brännäs (1980a). For interdependent models assumption (i) is clearly viólated and the con­ sequences of this is studied in Brännas (1978), which is based on the filtering approach suggested in Brännäs and Westlund (1978). This esti­ mator is approximative with respect to assumption (i). The estimator is evaluated in Brännäs and Westlund (1979), where the sensitivity to misspecification with respect to assumptions (ii), (iii) and (iv) are considered both for the reduced and the structural form, see also Brän­ näs (1980b). The possible consequences of a misspecified parameter

(17)

model studied in Brännas (1980a). The papers referred to in this para­ graph form the basis for the thesis and are summarized in more detail in the next sections.

3.2 Reduced form estimation

The application of the Kaiman filter to reduced forms is straightfor­ ward when assumptions (i)-(iv) above are satisfied. Under these and a model of the form (3.1)-(3.2) the statistical properties of the Kai­ man filter are good.

It is possible to show that $t|t an unbiased and consistent esti­ mator of the mean of ßt (e.g. Brännas and Westlund, 1980b). The filter is best linear, and best under normality assumptions, in the sense of minimum mean square error (e.g. Jazwinski, 1970). When, however, some or all of the assumptions are violated the performance of the estima­ tor is deteriorated. Jazwinski (1970) gives analytical expressions for the bias as a function of misspecifications of 3q|q, Q and R. The ex­ pressions are, however, too complex for making inferences of joint effects.

As long as the transition matrices At are equal to the identity matrix OLS (and GLS) give unbiased and consistent estimates of the mean

This is easily demonstrated by using the reformulation of Sant (1977) (Brännäs and Westlund, 1980b).

3.2.1 Stochastic regressors

In many models of economic phenomena it is not reasonable to make an explicit assumption of fixed regressors, though this for purely tech­ nical reasons may be convenient. Firstly, if lagged endogenous variab­ les are among the regressors assumption (i) is clearly violated. This case has been studied by Åström and Wittenmark (1971) and it results in the usual Kaiman filter. Secondly, by definition a variable is fixed if it can be predicted without error. Variables satisfying this are trend and intercept variables but most other economic variables must be regarded as stochastic. The argument is further amplified by the

(18)

common fact that an exogenous variable of one model well can serve as a random and endogenous variable in another model.

In Brännas (1978) assumption (i) is relaxed and it is shown that the filtering equations are given as

(3.9) ßtlt

-i

= At

e

t

_

1

|

t

_

1 (3.10) St|t— fix "1 (3.11) k; = Et]t.1 * ^|t-l + RI (3.12) rt|t. st|t.1-^t|t.1Bt|t.1 + Et <3'13)

The structure of these equations is the same as that of (3.4)-(3.8). However, it is immediately clear that xt is replaced by an(i

• • ßx • •

that a new covariance matrix has entered into K* in (3.11). In the covariance expression E i a new covariance matrix H has

en-. ßx ßx

tered, and the approximation depends on setting E£|t = ^t|t-l# T^ese changes all originate in the form of the innovation sequence

nt = (yt-yt|t-i)» Which incorporates the information at time t not previously known. In the fixed regressor case this takes the form

(3.14) nt = xt(Bt - Pt|t-1) • «t - +

i.e. it is a function of the model residual et and the prediction error in the parameter vector. If the regressors are stochastic the innovation sequence is given as

(3.15) nj - =t|t_1Bt|t_1 • it|t-x8t + «t " xt®t|t-1 * "tlt-l'tlt-l + et i.e. n* is a function of the model residual e and the prediction error

t|t-l' ^Ut now a^s? a function'of the prediction an<i the pre­ diction error

(19)

Since the Kalman gain K* and the covariance ^t|t are functions of the innovations the changes apparent in (3.9)-(3.13) follows. The effect

• Sx • •

of the incorporation of K* *-s that K* will become smaller which in turn implies a slower correction of old estimates in Stjt -Thus, it confirms the intuition in the sense that if uncertainty is increased new information is to be used conservatively. From a prac­ tical point of view these filtering equations are not directly appli­ cable. The covariance matrices need further consideration and a con­ venient stratey for obtaining must be determined. Only after this may it numerically be judged whether the modification with the increased computational burden is worthwhile.

3.2.2 Sensitivity to misspecifications

In Brännäs and Westlund (1979, 1980a) the robustness properties with respect to assumptions (ii), (iii), and (iv) are considered as a by­ product to the evaluation of the two stage Kaiman filter estimator suggested in Brännäs and Westlund (1978).

It is demonstrated by Monte Carlo simulations that the estimator of is remarkably robust with respect to the specification of Q and R (as­ sumption (ii)). The sensitivity to a misspecified $q|q (assumption (iv))

is greater and in particular the impact of an incorrect (assumption (iii)) is serious. These results are well in line with the results of earlier corresponding studies (McWhorter et al., 1976), and hence fur­ ther underline the need for research related to the estimation of the transition matrix and the initial parameter vector Sq|q*

3.2.3 Joint estimation of a time invariant transition matrix and the time-varying parameter vector

Motivated by the apparent sensitivity to misspecified transition matri­ ces Brännäs (1980a) suggests and to some extent evaluates an estimator for a time invariant transition matrix A, the parameter vector St, and the model residual covariance matrix R.

(20)

This estimator belongs to the class of prediction error minimizing techniques and is based on the likelihood of the prediction errbt se-* quence nt ~ yt~yt|t-l' where yt|t-l 0^ta^ne(^ from a Kaiman filter. By basing the likelihood on this sequence, the likelihood function is significantly simplified and the computational burden reduced. The estimates of A are obtained by nonlinear maximization of the concen­ trated likelihood function. The obtained estimates of A and R are sub­ stituted into the filtering equations to yield the desired estimates of 3t.

The identifiability questions for this estimation problem are discus­ sed in Tse and Weinert (1975) and in Pagan (1980). Some results on the asymptotic properties are given in Ljung (1978), Ljung and Caines (1979), and Pagan (1980).

In a small sample Monte Carlo study it is seen that the estimator per­ forms well in the sense of yielding small bias and mean square error. It is further demonstrated that the specification of the covariance matrix Q in this particular situation improves the bias properties, if increased. When the true parameter model is different from the one assumed, an increasing Q reduces the bias and improves the model fit. Generally, the bias properties of are promising and the technique computationally convenient.

It is possible to obtain estimates of 3q|q and Q by the same likeli­

hood function as long as the identifiability criteria of Pagan (1980) are satisfied.

3.3 Structural form estimation

Structural form estimation is in the general case different from re­ duced form estimation with respect to the presence of right hand endo­ genous variables. By this, assumption (i) of section 3.1 is violated, and further there exist nonzero correlations between these endogenous variables and the residuals. In the case of constant parameters, this implies that single equation estimators like OLS are biased even asymp­ totically, as would the Kaiman filter be in the present framework.

(21)

To the knowledge of the author, two approaches to structural form es­ timation, when the parameters are time-varying have been suggest ed. Aagaard-Svendsen (1979) suggests that the estimation is to be per­ formed over the linearized reduced form (with respect to structural parameters). The approach is thus an application of the extended Kaiman filter (e.g. Jazwinski, 1970). Aagaard-Svendsen applies the estimator to the estimation of constant parameters in a small model of the Danish economy.

An alternative approach is suggested by Brännas and Westlund (1978). This estimator is functionally parallel to two stage least squares, in the sense that right hand endogenous variables are replaced by in­ strumental variables (variables that are uncorrelated with the resi­ duals but correlated with the variables that are replaced). In a second stage the traditional Kaiman filter is applied in the same manner as OLS is applied in 2SLS. The instrumental variables are obtained by reg­ ressing each endogenous variable on the set of predetermined variables.

3.3.1 The estimator

The estimator suggested by Brännas and Westlund (1978) (see also Brännäs and Westlund, 1979) is based on the linear structural form

(3.16) yt = y;ct * *tBt + et - ztBt + et

where the parameters are assumed to vary according to

(3.17) 6t = At8t.j + wt.

In the first stage the reduced form corresponding to (3.16)-(3.17) is utilized to obtain yt|t = xt7Tt|t> where Trt|t are the reduced form para­ meter estimates. The estimation in stage one is suggested to be per­ formed by a Kaiman filter, where the a priori quantities are obtained from the structural form correspondents. In the second stage y^|t is used instead of the right hand endogenous y~ vector in (3.16) and the Kaiman filter applied a second time.

(22)

The estimating equations are thus given as (3.18) St|t_! " At et-l|t-l (3.19) (3.2°) Kt-st|t.lI;|tbt|trt|t.ili|t+ RS]"1 (3-21) £t|t = Et|t_j - Ktzt|tZt|t-1 (3-22> et|t = et|t-l * Kt<yt * zt|t6t|t-l)

where QS and RS are defined analogously to Q and R of section 3.1. The matrix zt|t °f explanatory variables is given as zt|t= ^t|t' xt^ "

3.3.2 An exact estimator

If the xfc matrix contains fixed exogenous "variables the reduced form estimator satisfies assumption (i) of section 3.1. On the other hand, the instrumental variable part of zt|t stochastic in irtjt an<* thus assumption (i) is violated in the second stage.

Brännäs (1978) recognizes this fact and studies the consequences of relaxing the assumption. It is shown that the impact of random reg-ressors in the present context is of the same kind as in the reduced form case. The estimator (cf. Brännäs and Westlund, 1978) is thus an approximative one and is shown to have a larger Kaiman gain. If y in (3.16) is assumed to be generated through y.t|t instead of yfc, the esti­ mator of Brännäs and Westlund (1978) would be an exact one.

It must be recognized, however, that the estimator of Brännäs and West-lund (1978) is a computationally convenient estimator, whereas the es­ timator of Brännäs (1978) is numerically complex and not of a fully recursive nature.

(23)

3.3.3 Sensitivity to misspecifications

The structural form estimator is for its use dependent on a priori spe­ cifications on model and parameter residual covariances, the initial parameter vector and the transition matrix in a still more tricky way than in the reduced form case. A natural approach to specifying these is to initialize in terms of the structural form and then to transform into reduced form quantities (cf. Brännäs and Westlund, 1979).

In Brännas and Westlund (1979, 1980a) the estimator is evaluated by Monte Carlo experiments, both in cases where initial specifications are correct and where misspecifications (in assumptions (ii)-(iv)) are present. With respect to bias and mean square error (MSE) the estima­ tor does well in the correctly specified cases, but also when the co-variances (QS and RS) are misspecified. The performance is deteriorated when 3q|q is misspecified and more so when the transition matrix is incorrect.

The results are well in line with earlier results from studies on the reduced form properties (e.g. McWhorter et al., 1976).

The estimator (2SKF) is compared with two stage least squares (2SLS) and OLS by Brännäs and Westlund (1980b). In a Monte Carlo study corre­ sponding to that of Brännäs and Westlund (1979) it is noticed that the bias of 2SLS is very close to that of 2SLS when the transition matrix is equal to the identity matrix. When structure two (At = 1.02*I) is utilized the bias properties of 2SLS are worsening. The MSE is through­ out considerably higher in 2SLS than in 2SKF. The performance of OLS is weaker than that of both 2SLS and 2SKF.

3.3.4 Empirical results

In an empirical application of both 2SKF and KF on the model of Brännäs and Eklöf (1980), Brännäs (1980b) analyses the robustness both with res­ pect to a priori specifications in the structural form and in the re­ duced form. It is observed that the terminal time estimates (N = 52) are rather insensitive to misspecifications. However, the impact on inter­

(24)

mediate time estimates is such that inferences about structural pro­ perties are hard to make when the specification in particular of 3q j and £q|q is uncertain.

In a forecasting comparison KF and 2SKF are seen to outperform 2SLS, while when forecasting over several steps ahead 2SLS, is in general better (see also Cooley, 1975, McWhorter et al., 1977, and Baudin and Westlund, 1980). The KF forecasts are slightly better than those of 2SKF. In a certainty equivalence control framework it is demonstrated that the impact of changes in parameter estimates is stronger than changes in the loss function, but less important than bad exogenous forecasts. In an ex-ante comparison it is seen that more stress is to be placed on the use of certain instrument variables than when using 2SLS. This matter is explained in terms of a more rapid adaption to new parameter values of the KF and 2SKF estimators.

3.4 Summarizing comments

The results reported on the application of the Kaiman filter in eco­ nometrics have focused at the estimation of time-varying parameters. The filter in itself is, of course, more general and can as long as the problem can be formulated in a form corresponding to (3.1)-(3.2) be applied. Examples of other applications are the incorporation of extra information in improving preliminary statistics (Conrad and Corrado, 1979), and the explicit treatment of measurement errors (e.g. Chow, 1975), and rational expectations (Wall, 1980).

In econometric applications the assumptions underlying the filtering equations are only seldom fulfilled. The research reported in Brännäs (1978, 1980a,b), and Brännäs and Westlund (1979) aims at relaxing and evaluating whether the assumptions are critical with respect to the estimates. These considerations are all important steps in gaining ex­ perience and knowledge for the further development in the area.

The evaluations are all concerned with small sample situations, as these are the important ones in most econometric applications. For such cases,

(25)

the present results may be regarded as predecessors to exact theore­ tical results, that are the ultimate goals. The asymptotic properties of the estimators are not explicitly dealt with.

As is quite evident from the results care should in particular be exer­ cised with respect to the initial parameter vector and its covariance as well as to the transition matrix. In a reduced form framework the technique utilized in Brännas (1980a) can cope with both of these prob­ lems. The empirical results of Brännäs (1980b) by and large support the findings of earlier studies with respect to time-varying parameters and their robustness. Further, the performance of 2SKF is seen to be close to that of KF, both in forecasting and control.

4. Some notes of further research

In the reduced form framework several of the more urgent research prob­ lems have been satisfactorily solved. By the identification criteria of Pagan (1980) the elements of A, ßt, Q and R may be uniquely estima­ ted. However, practical experience with the technique of Brännäs (1980a) and Pagan (1980) is still almost nonexistent, and the small sample pro­ perties only partly investigated (Brännäs, 1980a).

For structural form models several problems still wait for their solu­ tions. In particular, the question of identifiability must be satis­ factorily solved. Progress in this respect is believed to be achievable by the approach of Pagan (1980). As to the estimation of the necessary supplement information no solution has, to the author's knowledge, so far been offered. Quite evidently, however, the approach of extended Kaiman filtering seems a promising one, and the techniques of Brännäs (1980a) and Pagan (1980) are believed to be applicable.

(26)

References

Aagaard-Svendsen, R. (1979) Econometrics and Kaiman filtering. Ph.D. thesis. The Technical University of Denmark.

Äthans, M. (1974) The importance of Kaiman filtering methods for economic systems. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 3, 49-64.

Aoki, M. (1976) Optimal control and system theory in dynamic economic analysis. North-Holland. Amsterdam.

Äström, K.J. and Wittenberg, B. (1971) Problems of identification and control. Journal of Mathematical Analysis and Applications 34, 90-113.

Ball, R.J. (Chairman) (1978) Comittee on policy optimization: Report. HMSO. London.

Baudin, A. and Westlund, A. (1980) On the problem of structural insta­ bility in econometrics: A study of the US paper and pulp mar­ ket. Statistical Research Report 1980-7. University of Umeå. Belsley, D.A. (1973) On the determination of systematic parameter

variation in the linear regression model. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 2, 487-494.

Bowden, R.J. (1978) The econometrics of disequilibrium. North-Holland. Amsterdam.

Brown, R.L., Durbin, J. and Evans, J.M. (1975) Techniques for testing the constancy of regression relationships over time. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society B 37, 149-192.

K. (1978) On Kalman filtering in econometric systems. Statis­ tical Research Report 1978-8 (Revision 1980). University of Umeå.

K. (1980a) Joint estimation of parameters and their rate of change in varying parameter regression. Statistical Research Report 1980-6. University of Umeå.

K. (1980b) On the estimation of time-varying parameters for forecasting and control. Statistical Research Report 1980-10. University of Umeå.

K. and Eklöf, J.A. (1980) The Swedish balance of payments and international reserves: Modelling and control. Statistical Research Report 1980-5. University of Umeå.

Brännäs,

Brännäs,

Brännas,

(27)

Brännäs, K. and Westlund, A. (1978) On the recursive estimation of stochastic and time-varying parameters in econometric sys­ tems. Statistical Research Report 1978-7. University of Umeå. Brännäs, K. and Westlund, A. (1979) Robustness properties of a Kaiman filter estimator in interdependent systems with time-varying parameters. To appear in Charatsis, E.G. (Ed) Selected papers on contemporary econometric problems. North-Holland. Amster­ dam.

Brännäs, K. and Westlund, A. (1980a) On the recursive estimation of stochastic and time-varying parameters in econometric systems. In Iracki, K., Malanowski, K. and Walukiewicz, S. (Eds) Opti­ mization techniques. Springer-Verlag. Berlin.

Brännäs, K. and Westlund, A. (1980b) Statistical properties of the Kaiman filter in structural form estimation. Forthcoming. University of Umeå.

Cargill, T.F. and Meyer, R.A. (1978) The time varying response of in­ come to changes in monetary and fiscal policy. The Review of Economics and Statistics 60, 1-7.

Chow, G.C. (1960) Tests of the equality between two sets of coeffi­ cients in two linear regressions. Econometrica 28, 591-605. Chow, G.C. (1975) Analysis and control of dynamic economic systems.

Wiley. New York.

Conrad, W. and Corrado, C. (1979) Application of the Kaiman filter to revisions in monthly retail sales estimates. Journal of Eco­ nomic Dynamics and Control 1, 177-198.

Cooper, J.P. (1973) Time-varying regression coefficients: A mixed estimation approach and operational limitations of the gene­ ral Markov structure. Annals of Economic and Social Measure­ ment 2, 525-530.

Cooley, T.F. (1971) Estimation in the presence of sequential parame­ ter variation. Ph.D. thesis. University of Pennsylvania. Cooley, T.F. (1975) A comparison of robust and varying parameter esti­

mates of a macroeconometric model. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement' 4, 373-388.

Cooley, T.F. and Prescott, E.C. (1976) Estimation in the presence of stochastic parameter variation. Econometrica 44, 167-184.

(28)

Ferreira, P.E. (1975) A Bayesian analysis of a switching regression model: Known number of regimes. Journal of the American Sta­ tistical Association 70, 370-374.

Freebairn, J.W. (1978) Recursive coefficient estimates for the evalu­ ation of varying parameters. Australian Journal of Statistics 20, 219-228.

Garbade, K. (1977) Two methods for examining the stability of reg­ ression coefficients. Journal of the American Statistical Association 72, 54-63.

Goldfeld, S.M. and Quandt, R.E. (1972) Nonlinear methods in econo­ metrics. North-Holland. Amsterdam.

Hackl, P. and Katzenbeisser, W. (1978) On the adequacy of consumption functions for Austria. Empirical Economics 3, 227-239.

Intriligator, M.D. (1978) Econometric models, techniques, and appli­ cations. North-Holland. Amsterdam.

Jazwinski, A.H. (1970) Stochastic processes and filtering theory. Academic Press. New York.

Johnson, L.W. (1977) Stochastic parameter regression: An annotated bibliography. International Statistical Review 45, 257-272. Johnson, L.W. (1978) Regression with random coefficents. Omega 6,

71-81.

Johnson, L.W. (1980) Stochastic parameter regression: An additional annotated bibliography. International Statistical Review 48, 95-102.

Kaiman, R.E. (1960) A new approach to linear filtering and prediction problems. Trans. ASME Journal of Basic Engineering 82, 35-45.

Ljung, L. (1978) Convergence analysis of parametric identification methods. IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control AC-23, 770-783.

Ljung, L. and Caines, P.E. (1979) Asymptotic normality of prediction error estimators for approximate system models. Stochastics 3, 29-46.

Lucas, R.E. (1976) Econometric policy evaluation: A critique. In Brun­ ner, K. and Meitzer, A.H. (Eds) The Phillips curve and labour markets. Carnagie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy.

(29)

McWhorter, A., Spivey, W.A. and Wrobleski, W.J. (1976) A sensitivity analysis of varying parameter econometric models. Internatio­ nal Statistical Review 44, 265-282.

Morgenstern, 0. (1963) On the accuracy of economic observations. 2nd edition. Princeton University Press. Princeton.

Preston, A. and Wall, K.D. (1973) Some aspects of the use of state space models in econometrics. Technical report. Imperial College. London.

Pagan, A. (1980) Some identification and estimation results for reg­ ression models with stochastically varying coefficients. Journal of Eco nometrics 13, 341-363.

Poirier, D.J. (1976) The econometrics of structural change. Nerth-Holland. Amsterdam.

Quandt, R.E. (1958) The estimation of the parameters of a linear reg­ ression system obeying two separate regimes. Journal of the American Statistical Association 53, 873-880.

Quandt, R.E. (1960) Tests of the hypothesis that a linear regression system obeys two separate regimes. Journal of the American Statistical Association 55, 324-330.

Quandt, R.E. (1972) A new approach to estimating switching regres­ sions. Journal of the American Statistical Association 67, 306-310.

Rosenberg, B. (1973a) A survey of stochastic parameter regression. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 2, 381-397. Rosenberg, B. (1973b) Random coefficient models; The analysis of a

cross section of time series by stochastically convergent pa­ rameter regression. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 2, 399-428.

Sant, D.T. (1977) Generalized least squares applied to time-varying parameter models. Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 6, 301-314.

(30)

Swamy, P.A.V.B. (1971) Statistical inference in random coefficient regression models. Springer-Verlag. Berlin.

Swamy, P.A.V.B, and Tinsley, P.A. (1980) Linear prediction and esti­ mation methods for regression models with stationary stochas­ tic coefficients. Journal of Econometrics 12, 103-142.

Tse, E. and Weinert, H.L. (1975) Structure determination and para­ meter identification for multivariable stochastic linear sys­ tems, IEEE Transactions on Automatic Control AC-20, 603-612. Wall, K.D. (1980) Generalized expectations modeling in

macroeconomet-rics. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 2, 161-184. Wallis, K.F. (1980) Econometric implications of the rational expecta­

tions hypothesis. Econometrica 48, 49-73.

Zackrisson, U. (1977) Prognosvärde och prognosintressenter. Technical Report. University of Umeå.

Zellner, A. (1971) An introduction to Bayesian inference in economet­ rics. Wiley. New York.

References

Related documents

46 Konkreta exempel skulle kunna vara främjandeinsatser för affärsänglar/affärsängelnätverk, skapa arenor där aktörer från utbuds- och efterfrågesidan kan mötas eller

Däremot är denna studie endast begränsat till direkta effekter av reformen, det vill säga vi tittar exempelvis inte närmare på andra indirekta effekter för de individer som

Parallellmarknader innebär dock inte en drivkraft för en grön omställning Ökad andel direktförsäljning räddar många lokala producenter och kan tyckas utgöra en drivkraft

I dag uppgår denna del av befolkningen till knappt 4 200 personer och år 2030 beräknas det finnas drygt 4 800 personer i Gällivare kommun som är 65 år eller äldre i

Generell rådgivning, såsom det är definierat i den här rapporten, har flera likheter med utbildning. Dessa likheter är speciellt tydliga inom starta- och drivasegmentet, vilket

Det har inte varit möjligt att skapa en tydlig överblick över hur FoI-verksamheten på Energimyndigheten bidrar till målet, det vill säga hur målen påverkar resursprioriteringar

Detta projekt utvecklar policymixen för strategin Smart industri (Näringsdepartementet, 2016a). En av anledningarna till en stark avgränsning är att analysen bygger på djupa

DIN representerar Tyskland i ISO och CEN, och har en permanent plats i ISO:s råd. Det ger dem en bra position för att påverka strategiska frågor inom den internationella