• No results found

How population ageing affects technological innovation in perspective of human capital

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "How population ageing affects technological innovation in perspective of human capital"

Copied!
45
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

How population ageing affects

technological innovation in

perspective of human capital

Master’s thesis in Economics Authors: Shirang Wang Tutors: Emma Lappi Marcel Garz Jönköping 08 2019

(2)

Master Thesis in Economics

Title: How population ageing affects technological innovation in perspective of human capital

Authors: Shirang Wang Tutor: Emma Lappi Marcel Garz Date: 2019-08-28

Key terms: technological innovation, population ageing, knowledge spillover, factor analysis

Abstract

Based on panel data collected from 41 countries over the period 2007-2017, this paper analysis how population ageing affects technological innovation through three aspects from the perspective of human capital: the loss of knowledge and talents; reverse force and knowledge spillover. In this paper, the technological innovation index (TII) is calculated by using the factor analysis method. Further with this, a fixed-effects regression model is applied to discover that population exerts a significant positive effect on technological innovation through reverse force, while exerts negative effects on technological innovation through the loss of knowledge and talents and knowledge spillover.

(3)

Table of contents

1.Background ... 1

2.Literature Review ... 4

2.1 Population and technology ... 4

2.2 Population ageing and technological innovation ... 6

2.2.1 The loss of knowledge and talents ... 8

2.2.2 Reverse force ... 9

2.2.3 Knowledge spillover ... 9

2.3 Technological innovation index ... 11

3. Data ... 14

4. Empirical Analysis ... 16

4.1 Calculation of technological innovation index based on factor analysis ... 16

4.1.1 Variable selection and correlation analysis ……...…………...………..18

4.1.2 Factor analysis suitability test……….19

4.1.3 Comprehensive evaluation of technological innovation index………..….20

4.1.4 Technology innovation index comprehensive score ranking………..23

4.2 Effects of how population ageing affects technological innovation………….….23

4.2.1 Model ………...………..24

4.2.2 Stationarity test………..………..…….……..25

4.2.3 KAO panel co-integration test………...………..…….…..…26

4.3 Regression analysis………..………..………….…..27

5. Conclusion …...………..31

(4)

Tables

Table 1- Independent variables and control variables………14

Table 2 - Descriptive statistics………14

Table 3 - Correlations analysis………18

Table 4 - KMO and Bartlett's test ……….…….19

Table 5 - Total variance explained ……….……20

Table 6 - Rotated component matrix ………..21

Table 7 - Component score coefficient matrix ………...21

Table 8 - Technology innovation index comprehensive score ranking …………..…23

Table 9 - Panel unit root test ………...25

Table 10 - KAO cointegration test ………..……26

Table 11 - F-test and Hausman test………..………28

Table 12 - Residual cross-section dependence test and panel cross-section heteroscedasticity LR test ………..………..…29

(5)

1 1. Background

From the 1980s onwards, population has been an issue that attracts relatively less attention as the endogenous growth theory emerges and develops (Lucas, 2004).

Nevertheless, the issue of ageing population has worsened on a continued basis over the recent years. As indicated by World Population Prospects (2019), the proportion of older people (over 65 years old) has increased from 5% to 9% during 1960- 2018. By 2050, this number is expected to rise to 16%, while in the more developed areas like Europe and North America, a quarter of the population will be over 65 years; the proportion will be doubled even in less developed areas like North Africa, Asia, Latin America and Caribbean.

Population ageing and the decline in the proportion of working-age population has a profound impact on economic and social development on a global scale: population aging has aroused people's concerns about taxation, savings, per capita income growth, labor supply, medical expenditures and economic security for the elderly. How to address the challenge posed by ageing population has drawn increasing attention from both the government and the academic field (Bloom et al., 2015). To mitigate the negative impact made by ageing population, many countries have taken corresponding measures: delaying the retirement age or taking incentives to delay retirement; overhauling pension financing; reducing welfare growth; expanding investment made in education and improving the participation of women, immigrants and the elderly to increase effective workforce.

(6)

2

In the academic field, the concept of innovation can be traced back to 1912, in the Theory of Economic Development, the innovation theory was first proposed by Schumpeter (1912), he also proposes that innovation is introducing the new combination of a new production factor and a new production condition into the production system. The scope of Schumpeter's innovative notion is widespread, which encompasses technological innovation and non-technical organizational innovation. Back in the 1960s, Rostow (1962) puts forward the Rostovian take-off model, where the notion of “innovation” was developed into “technological innovation” and “technological innovation” was raised to take up the dominant position of “innovation”. Since the 1970s, the studies conducted into innovation were advanced and systematic theories started to develop. Prominent scholar Freeman (1973) holds the belief that technological innovation represents the first transition of technology to being commercialized.

In the exogenous growth model established by Solow and Swan in 1956, technical progress was added to the production function as an exogenous variable, which better explains the economic growth. In the endogenous growth theory formed in the mid-1980s, some economists like Romer (1994) and Lucas (1988) begin to regard technological progress as an endogenous variable, and since then technological innovation has been considered as a driving variable of economic growth and development.

(7)

3

According to the OECD (2004), technology and innovation are the key factors in improving productivity, employment, economic growth and individuals' well-being. On the firm level, Aghion and Howitt (1992) indicate that in the context of endogenous growth theory, innovative companies tend to executive monopoly policy to take the leading position in market competition, thereby increasing economic productivity. On the national level, by studying the impact of technological innovation on economic growth among 12 countries in Latin America, Bujari and Martínez (2016) find that innovation activities such as R&D investment and patent applications have important implications for economic growth. In addition, R&D will promote the economic growth through the improvement on total factor productivity. Litsareva (2007) find that the Asia-Pacific region has greatly enhanced its regional competitiveness by increasing its knowledge economy and pursuing positive policies for innovative enterprises and high-tech industries. By studying the R&D expenditure, innovation and economic growth of 13 high-income OECD economies, Guloglu and Tekin (2012) find that R&D investment increases with market size which could generate innovation and increase economic growth, successful innovation activities can also attract a higher investment in the R&D department.

Previous researches about population ageing predominantly concentrated on how population ageing affects savings, labor supply, government public expenditure and social security. The studies on ageing population and technological innovation are still relatively rare, so given the increasingly important economic status of population

(8)

4

ageing and technological innovation, an analysis of the association between ageing population and technological innovation will be performed from the perspective of human capital in this paper.

The layout of the paper is as follows. Section 1 introduces the background, Section 2 presents literature review, Section 3 lists the relevant data, Section 4 conducts an empirical analysis, and Section 5 presents the conclusion drawn from the study.

2.Literature Review

2.1 population and technology

The exacerbation of population ageing and the rising status of scientific technological innovation in economic growth have composed the two main backgrounds of this paper. Besides, there are some classic theories in respect of the association between population and technology in economics.

Malthus (1798) considers population as an endogenous variable in the process of economic growth: when average income increases due to the progress in technology or the discovery of new resources, it is always accompanied with population growth, which in turn brings a decline in average income. In the long run, the average income level remains the same, technological progress cannot improve individuals’ living condition, this is known as “Malthusian trap”.

As explained by Galor (2005), the " Malthusian trap " has dominated a period of human history for quite a long time. However, the situation has changed since the industrial

(9)

5

revolution. With the rapid growth of productivity brought by large-scale industrial production, average income has increased rapidly, individuals finally jump out of the “Malthusian trap” and truly experienced the benefits of technological progress.

Despite the increasing size of the population, the population growth rate is not growing continuously. According to Warren (1929), after the population expansion that lasted for some time, the leading developed countries and some developing countries around the world have undergone a decrease in population growth rate or even transformed into a negative population growth rate country, which is known as "demographic transition".

When discussing demographic transition, the demographic dividend is also a notion worth mentioning. According to Bloom and Williamson (1998), the demographic dividend period usually refers to the historical period in which the proportion of the working-age (15-64 years old) population in the total population of a country continues to rise during the development process, with that of juvenile and elderly population in decline on a continued basis. As reported by Lee, Mason and Miller (2000), during the demographic dividend period, due to changes in age structure, sufficient labor can provide positive support for economic growth, and the country will thus receive the first demographic dividend. Nevertheless, various factors like the prolonged average life expectancy, the growing personal savings and assets, and the expansion of high-quality labor force during the demographic dividend period will exert a positive effect on economic

(10)

6

growth continuously in the wake of the first demographic dividend period, which is known as the second demographic dividend. During the second demographic dividend period, population ageing will play a vital role in the demographic trend, and it will have a permanent positive impact if the capital received from the first demographic dividend will be directed at making investment in technology. As the research object in this paper is population ageing, to prevent the impact of the population base on the results, the total population will be taken as a control variable.

To explain the economic inequalities in various countries and regions, Galor (2012) proposes unified growth theory and explains the importance of human capital in the production process. From the Malthusian trap to sustained economic growth, there is a significant increase in technology and a slowdown or decline in population growth. Also, the investment in human capital triggered by technology progress can further stimulate technological progress, thereby resulting in a sustained economic growth.

2.2 Population ageing and technological innovation

When reviewing previous literatures, some studies discover that population ageing exerts an adverse effect on technological innovation. By studying the case of Japan and China separately, Tian Xueyuan et al. (1990) and Yao Dongmin et al. (2017) all indicate that population ageing will put more strain on pension and erode scientific research resources, thus exerting a negative effect on technological innovation.

(11)

7

In some studies, it has also been discovered that population ageing has positive impact on technological innovation. Frosch and Tivig (2009) applly patents to denote technological innovations and discovered that the number of patents has positive association with the percentage of the elderly population in Germany.

There are also studies where population ageing is discovered to create both positive and negative effects on technological innovation. By studying the case of China, Wang Wei and Jiang Zhenmao (2016) find that population aging has both positive and negative impacts on technological innovation from the perspectives of individuals, enterprises and regions. Population ageing is speculated to impede technological progress by putting more pressure on pension. Besides, it may also prompt individuals to pay more attention to human capital investment and transform economic growth methods to promote technological progress.

As reported by Rumberger (1981), education brings various benefits to both individuals and society. It plays a significant role in developing skilled workforce, thus achieving social mobility and sustained economic growth. Galindo (2013) indicates that a better economy situation can also provide better material conditions for improving the capability of technological innovation capability in the region. Von Tunzelmann (1997) points out that industrialization may have a promoting effect or hindrance effect on technological innovation. On the one hand, the achievement of inventions requires the assistance of industrialization. On the other hand, if a specific region places too much emphasis on industrial production and thus overlook other factors such as technology

(12)

8

research and development, it may also adversely affect the improvement of technological innovation.

In summary, population ageing could affect technological innovation of a country or region. Based on these studies on population ageing and technological innovation, this paper will analyze the association from the following aspects: the loss of knowledge and talents, reverse force effect and knowledge spillover. Total population, industrialization rate, education and GDP will be taken as control variables.

2.2.1 The loss of knowledge and talents

It is challenging for elderly workers to embrace information technology, which will reduce the proportion of high-skilled labor in the R&D department. Behaghel and Greenan (2010) find that when companies apply advanced information technology, older employees are less likely to receive training in computer applications and teamwork. Noda (2011) uses product quality improvement index as a proxy for technological innovation and progress and finds that the change in demographic structure resulting from population ageing can shrink the proportion of high-skilled employees in the R&D department, thus exerting negative effects on the innovation ratio. Dixon (2003) also explains that increased information technology penetration rate may put older workers at a disadvantage in the labor market. Additionally, he also points out that workforce skills remain reliant on knowledge stocks obtained before entering the labor market or in the initial stage of a personal career. As the average age of labor participants rises, this skill inventory may become increasingly obsolete and

(13)

9

bring negative effects on innovation and productivity. This paper will use the number of technicians and researchers in R&D department to see if there is a reduction of the high-skilled labor force or not.

2.2.2 Reverse force

Ageing population may have a positive impact on the labor productivity. Many scholars notice that with population ageing, the scarcity of labor will produce a “reverse force effect”, which will compel enterprises to apply more machineries and equipment to enhance labor efficiency. As indicated by Scarth (2002), Lee and Mason (2010), in the case of labor shortage, to keep the momentum of economic development, society will be reliant on the improvement of labor skills to replace the low-skilled labor, thereby increasing labor efficiency. Romer (1987) and Feyrer (2007) also prove that population ageing could be conducive to enhance labor productivity. The studies as mentioned above reveal that with the assistance of “reverse force effect”, population ageing can exert a positive impact on the labor efficiency for scientific research workers.

In this paper, high-technology export is taken as a proxy to assess the labor efficiency of the labor market to verify whether population aging has a reverse force effect for technological innovation.

2.2.3 Knowledge spillover

The knowledge spillover between different age groups can be positive or negative. Disney (1996) indicates that mature labors tend to have a higher average work

(14)

10

experience, which may have a positive impact on productivity. As discovered by Ashworth (2006), Kuhn and Hetze (2007), from the perspective of skills training, experience transmission and knowledge loss, population ageing may have a negative impact on the level of human capital in R&D department.

Audretsch (1995) proposes the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship and explains that knowledge spillover can be expressed in the form of startup companies and self-employment rate, talents can use their knowledge in startup companies and generate knowledge spillovers. By studying the case of Germany, Audretsch and Lehmann (2005) use the number of startups near German universities to measure knowledge spillover and find that the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship also works in regions and industries.

Jaffe, Trajtenberg and Henderson (1993) point out that knowledge spillover does show traces and exists in the form of patent inventions on a frequent basis. Acs, Anselin, and Varga (2002) also validate patents as a technological change and novel knowledge. Zachariadis (2003) studies US manufacturing and find that the increase in R&D investment spurs an increase in patents, which in turn leads to greater technological advances, thereby promoting economic growth. Meanwhile, there are also opponents for using patent application to evaluate knowledge spillover. Bottazzi and Peri (2003) indicate that unregistered knowledge will be missed by only using the patent application. Griliches (1990) explains that there are significant differences in the technical and

(15)

11

economic value of various patents, which is unmeasurable, using patent applications as a proxy means that the patents are all treated equally.

Since this paper studies the knowledge spillover caused by population ageing among countries, given the unequal national policies for startup companies and different university academic standards, this paper will use the number of patent applications to measure the knowledge spillover of the entire labor market.

2.3 Technological Innovation Index

From previous researches, most of the articles cover the research and development result of technological innovation. Meanwhile, the advancement of technological innovation is closely associated with a combination of education, financial backing, infrastructure and other factors. To measure the technological innovation index comprehensively, factor analysis method will be taken to ensure the objectivity of the research results.

By using the knowledge production function, Griliches (1979) finds that investment in R&D may increase the company's knowledge stock, thereby bringing innovation and higher productivity. Crepon, Duguet, and Mairesse (1998) establish the CDM model, which lays the foundation for many innovative studies. By studying innovation at the firm level in Europe, they prove that R&D investment can contribute to innovation output, thereby increasing productivity and economic growth. By studying the case of France, Germany, Spain and UK, Griffith et al. (2006) also verify that companies with higher R&D investment are more likely to achieve innovation. To reflect the capability

(16)

12

to support regional innovation from the economic base, this paper will take R&D expenditure as a proxy for measuring technological innovation index.

Leonard (1992) points out that the continuously updated knowledge stock enables the company to continue exploring and keep the innovation vitality, so as not to jump into the comfort zone and lose competitiveness. By studying the case of Korea, OECD (2000) finds that developing countries that have successfully transitioned to knowledge-based countries will have strong competitiveness due to the booming development of high-tech industries and information and communication technologies, the knowledge stocks have become a core factor for the global economic and social development. Similar with Kumar et al. (2016), scientific and technical journal articles will be taken as an indicator to represent knowledge stock.

With the release of the Global Information Technology Report (2006), the world headed into the fourth industrial revolution, where innovation is increasingly reliant on digital technologies and emerging business models. Countries, enterprises and individuals will have more reliance on digital technology than the past. Meanwhile, the advanced Information Communications Technology (ICT) facilitates the production and communication of products, also contributes to the innovation system through increased productivity and efficiency, reduced transaction costs, improved market access and sustained growth (Baller, Dutta & Lanvin, 2016). In this paper, Mobile Cellular Subscriptions and Secure Internet Servers will be used as proxies to demonstrate the ICT level.

(17)

13

By studying the association of education, innovation and economic growth in China, Zhou and Luo (2018) find that investing in tertiary education can improve the scientific literacy of the nation and gradually increase the accumulation of human capital, thus bringing about technological innovation and progress. In addition, technological innovation and technological advancement will further promote economic growth. Finally, Economic growth makes more educational investment possible, thus promoting technological innovation and progress. In this paper, expenditure on tertiary education will be taken as a proxy for measuring technological innovation index.

As indicated by Erdal and Göçer, (2015), foreign direct investment (FDI) is one of the most important factors for achieving high economic growth in developing countries and regions. With financial capital, technical knowledge and management expertise obtained from FDI, host countries can greatly promote the productivity and innovation activities. In addition to obtaining monopoly rights, tax and cost concessions (Erdal & Göçer, 2015), there will be a R&D spillover effect in home countries through outward FDI, which could promote domestic innovation (Alazzawi, 2012). Considering the positive effect of FDI on both home and host countries, this paper will take FDI as a proxy for measuring technological innovation index.

In general, this paper will take expenditure on tertiary education, R&D expenditure, scientific and technical journal articles, FDI, mobile cellular subscriptions and secure Internet servers as proxies to evaluate technological innovation index.

(18)

14 3. Data

To observe how population ageing affects technological innovation from a broader perspective, all countries with sufficient data will be taken into consideration in this paper. Due to the large amount of missing data, this study deleted some national samples; for a small amount of missing yearly data, use moving average to complete missing values. After data manipulation, the entire database involves 41 countries,in which the composition of developed and developing countries is relatively average, the time period is from 2007 to 2017, all original data before per capita processing are collected from the World Bank Open Data. The technological innovation index system involves Expenditure on tertiary education (% of government expenditure on education), Research and development expenditure (% of GDP), Scientific and technical journal articles (per 100 people), Mobile cellular subscriptions (per 100 people), Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP) and Secure Internet servers (per 1 million people).

Independent variables and control variables are shown in table 1, corresponding descriptive statistics are shown in table 2.

Table 1. Independent variables and control variables Age dependency ratio, old (% of working-age

population) ---ADR

The ratio of people age over 64 to the working-age (15-64) population, reflect the situation of population ageing

Technicians & Researchers in R&D (per million people) --- TRD

Use interaction term ADR*TRD to reflect the reduction of the high-skilled labor force in R&D department

(19)

15 High-technology exports(current US$)--- HTE

Use interaction term ADR*THE to reflect the reverse force

Patent applications ((per 100 people) --- PA Use interaction term ADR*PA to reflect knowledge spillover.

GDP per capita (current US$) --- GDP Represent the economic development situation. Industrialization rate --- IND Represent the industrialization situation. Government expenditure on education, total (%

of GDP) --- EDU

Reflect financial support for potential knowledge innovation.

Population, total --- POP Reflect the overall population base

Table 2. Descriptive Statistics

Variable Obs Mean Std.Dev. Min Max

TII 451 0 .758 -2.049 2.948 ADR 451 20.646 7.461 7.104 36.276 LNTRD 451 7.639 1.14 3.665 9.201 LNPA 451 6.48 2.534 .693 12.596 LNHTE 451 22.07 2.327 15.91 26.121 EDU 451 5.314 1.32 2.779 9.51 IND 451 25.766 6.453 9.368 42.916 LNGDP 451 9.72 .951 7.115 11.543 LNPOP 451 16.376 1.541 12.649 19.6

The difference between the maximum and the minimum value of Age dependency ratio is massive, which indicates that there is a considerable difference in the Age dependency ratio between different countries. The mean value of Industrialization rate is 25.766, with the range between 9.368 and 42.916, which indicates that there is a significant fluctuation in industrialization situation among different countries.

(20)

16 4.Empirical Analysis

This paper takes the panel data of 41 countries (excluding countries with severe data loss) from 2007 to 2017 as the research sample, and panel regression is performed to conduct empirical research into the impact of population aging on technological innovation. Technological innovation index is used in this paper to quantify technological innovation, which is a comprehensive index calculated by the factor analysis method. Therefore, this empirical analysis consists of two major sections.: one is the measurement of technological innovation index, the other is to perform panel data regression to analysis the effects of population ageing on technological innovation. The steps to carry out factor analysis in this paper is following a guide book written by Paul (1994).

4.1 Calculation of Technological Innovation Index Based on Factor Analysis

As indicated by Archibugi and Coco (2005), the most common way to obtain a compound variable is to weight the indicators together with estimated weights, but the choice of indicators and weights is sometimes not objective enough. The factor analysis method proposed by Adelman and Morris (1965) can be recombined based on the information of the original variables to find the common factors, thus simplifying the data to obtain a more objective compound variable.

Factor analysis is primarily reliant on the idea of dimensionality reduction. Compared with multivariate regression, factor analysis is capable to prevent the problem of

(21)

17

multicollinearity in case there are a larger number of variables, and to extract multiple linear combinations from the original variables while ensuring that majority of the information is retained. This is conducive to reproducing the relationship of the original variables in an efficient way, thus achieving the goal of dimensionality reduction. An n-dimensional original random variable can be written as:

Y = (Y$, Y&, … Y()*

The linear replacement can be expressed as:

(F$, F&, … F()* = AY

Where A is an n-dimensional vector. When the variance of F$ is sufficiently large, F$ is capable to encompass as much information as possible on X. Other F- also requires as much information as possible that contains the original variable Y, but it is incapable to cover the previously reserved F$ information, which means the two main factors are irrelevant to each other, and the covariance is 0. The most common method of extracting factors is the standard proposed by Kaiser(1960), which is to keep factors with eigenvalues that are greater than 1. Griden (2001) also explains that indicators with eigenvalues less than 1 are considered unstable, and their interpretation of the overall variable is low, so it is not recommended to keep them in the analysis. So the number of principal components in this paper is premised on the standard that eigenvalues are greater than 1. After the principal component is determined, the scores of the variables on the principal component can be ascertained. Subsequently, the

(22)

18

principal component factors are named based on the rotated load matrix, and the comprehensive scores of the variables can be obtained by calculation.

4.1.1 Variable Selection and Correlation Analysis

Tertiary Education, Research and Development Expenditure (R&D expenditure), Scientific and Technical Journal Articles (STJA), FDI, Mobile Cellular Subscriptions (MCS) and Secure Internet Servers (SIS) are selected as proxies of technological innovation index in this paper. A correlation analysis is conducted in Table 3. As shown in the result, there is a significant correlation between the four correlation coefficients, for which it is sensible to conduct factor analysis with these four factors. Despite this, it requires further testing to ascertain whether it is appropriate or not.

Table3. Correlations analysis Tertiary

Education

R&D expenditure

STJA FDI MCS SIS

Tertiary Education 1 R&D expenditure .276** 1 STJA .336** .798** 1 FDI -.075 -.097* -.066 1 MCS .207** .149** .250** -.050 1 SIS .113* .238** .349** -.025 .119* 1

**. Correlation is significant at the 0.01 level (2-tailed). *. Correlation is significant at the 0.05 level (2-tailed)

(23)

19 4.1.2 Factor analysis suitability test

This paper uses SPSS to perform Bartlett test of Sphericity and Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin (KMO)Measure of Sampling Adequacy, the specific results are shown in table 4 below.

Table 4. KMO and Bartlett's Test

Kaiser-Meyer-Olkin Measure of Sampling Adequacy. .609 Bartlett's Test of Sphericity Approx. Chi-Square 615.013

df 15

Sig. .000

The KMO value is calculated by making comparison of the correlation coefficients for all variables. As explained by Cerny and Kaiser (1977), a larger KMO value indicates that it is more appropriate to conduct factor analysis, if KMO value is below 0.6, then there is no sufficient sample. The KMO value for this paper is between 0.60 and 0.69, which is mediocre but still acceptable.

As explained by Snedecor and William (1989), Bartlett's Test of Sphericity can be used to check the redundancy between variables. From the result, the chi-square value of the test is 615.013, and the P-value is less than 0.05, which means there is no redundancy between variables, for which the principal component analysis can be conducted in line with the standard judgment criteria.

(24)

20

4.1.3 Comprehensive evaluation of technological innovation index

From the Rotation Sums of Squared Loadings, the cumulative interpretation rate of the first two factors to the sample variance is 66.845% (the criterion for the selected factor is that the eigenvalue is greater than or equal to 1), which means that Tertiary Education and R&D expenditure can explain 66.845% information of the original variable.

Table 5. Total Variance Explained

Component

Initial Eigenvalues

Extraction Sums of Squared

Loadings Rotation Sums of Squared Loadings

Total

% of

Variance Cumulative % Total

% of

Variance Cumulative % Total

% of Variance Cumulative % Tertiary Education 1.269 37.811 37.811 1.269 37.811 37.811 1.170 34.834 34.834 R&D expenditure 1.003 26.711 64.522 1.003 26.711 64.522 1.202 32.011 66.845 STJA .945 15.748 70.270 FDI .857 14.280 84.550 MCS .742 12.368 96.917 SIS .185 3.083 100.000

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis.

From Rotated Component Matrix, R&D expenditure and STJA have higher loads on the main factor Tertiary Education, while Tertiary Education and MCS have higher loads on the main factor R&D expenditure. Then calculate the scores of the main factors by the factor score coefficient matrix and comprehensively evaluate technological innovation index.

(25)

21

Table 6. Rotated Component Matrixa Component

Tertiary Education R&D expenditure

Tertiary Education .401 .445 R&D expenditure .824 .215 STJA .888 .219 FDI .183 -.852 MCS .274 .420 SIS .578 -.084

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis. Rotation Method: Varimax with Kaiser Normalization. a. Rotation converged in 3 iterations.

Then calculate the scores of the main factors by the factor score coefficient matrix and comprehensively evaluate technological innovation index.

Table 7. Component Score Coefficient Matrix Component

Tertiary Education R&D expenditure

Tertiary Education .122 .323 R&D expenditure .392 .029 STJA .424 .020 FDI .269 -.812 MCS .060 .327 SIS .322 -.193

Extraction Method: Principal Component Analysis. Rotation Method: Varimax with Kaiser Normalization. Component Scores.

(26)

22

The main component scores of each country can be calculated with the result obtained from Component Score Coefficient Matrix, the calculation formula is:

F. = A-.y

-Where i=1,2…4,j=1,2(stands for 2 main Component), A-. represents the factor score of the i-th variable of the j-th principal factor. Based on the variance contribution rate and weight of each factor, the total factor score of the main components of each country can be determined, which is:

Y=(34.834%*F$+32.011%*F&)/ 66.845

4.1.4 Technology innovation index comprehensive score ranking

This paper ranks the average scores of the composite factors for 41 sample countries from 2007 to 2017. From the result in table 8, the ranking of each country’s technological innovation index roughly conforms to its economic development level. The countries with higher levels of economic development tend to manifest relatively better technological innovation capabilities. In contrast, the countries with lower levels of economic development tend to show lower technological innovation capabilities. The US shows the highest technological innovation index, followed by some European countries. Moreover, there is also a significant difference discovered in the comprehensive innovation index of every single country.

(27)

23

Table 8. Technology innovation index comprehensive score ranking Country Average

score sort Country

Average

score sort Country

Average

score sort Finland 1.3468 1 Lithuania 0.2329 15 Cyprus -0.4454 29 Singapore 1.2730 2 Italy 0.1695 16 Argentina -0.4560 30 Denmark 1.2475 3 France 0.1456 17 Bulgaria -0.4600 31 Sweden 1.0985 4 Malaysia 0.1443 18 Latvia -0.4693 32 Austria 1.0778 5 Serbia 0.0229 19 Chile -0.5765 33 Norway 0.7311 6 Spain -0.0027 20 Brazil -0.5859 34 Germany 0.7298 7 Portugal -0.0524 21 Thailand -0.7005 35 United States 0.6000 8 Ukraine -0.0553 22 Costa

Rica -0.7167 36 Iceland 0.5704 9 Poland -0.1023 23 Colombia -0.8089 37 Korea, South 0.3934 10 Slovakia -0.2098 24 Mexico -0.9361 38 Estonia 0.3309 11 Romania -0.2955 25 Malta -0.9562 39

United

Kingdom 0.3197 12 Hungary -0.3139 26 Guatemala -1.0845 40 New Zealand 0.3006 13 Tunisia -0.3313 27 Moldova -1.0869 41 Czech Republic 0.2809 14 Ecuador -0.3696 28

4.2 Effects of how population ageing affects technological innovation

On the previous section, this paper obtained the core variable --- technological innovation index through the factor analysis method. The following is a regression of the panel data, aims to analyze how population ageing affects technological innovation.

(28)

24 4.2.1 Model

Similar with Behaghel, Caroli and Roger (2013), this paper will use interaction terms to capture the effects of population ageing on technological innovation, 3 following models will be established as followed: Equation (1) is applied to test the loss of knowledge and talents. Equation (2) is applied to test the knowledge spillover resulting from population aging. Equation (3) is applied to test the reverse force effect.

TII-35$ADR-3×LNTRD-3+ β&ADR-3<LNGDP-3?Ind-3+ βBEDU-3ELNPOP-3-3 (1)

TII-35$ADR-3×LNPA-3+ β&ADR-3<LNGDP-3?Ind-3+ βBEDU-3ELNPOP-3-3 (2)

TII-35$ADR-3×LNHTE-3+ β&ADR-3<LNGDP-3?Ind-3+ βBEDU-3ELNPOP-3-3 (3)

Where i indicates for country, t denotes for year, TII refers to Technological Innovation Index, ADR represents Age dependency ratio, old (% of working-age population), TRD stands for Technicians & Researchers in R&D (per million people), PA indicates for Patent applications, and HTE stands for High-technology exports. LNGDP, IND, EDU, LNPOP are control variables, indicates for the natural logarithm of GDP per capita, industrialization rate, the proportion of total education expenditure to GDP and total population respectively; ε-3 is the error term , β5…βE are the parameters to be

(29)

25

(2) is applied to test the knowledge spillover resulting from population aging. Equation (3) is applied to test the reverse force effect.

4.2.2 Stationarity test

Although this paper selects a panel data from 2007 to 2017, to prevent spurious regression, this paper will conduct unit root test on each variable. The results of LLC test (Levin, Lin & James, 2002), ADF test (Dickey & Fuller, 1979) and PP test (Phillips & Perron, 1988) are presented in table 10. From the panel unit root test, the variables are stable after first-order difference.

Table 9. Panel unit root test Variable

LLC Test ADF Test PP Test

Stationarity Statistic Prob.** Statistic Prob.** Statistic Prob.**

TII 1.02851 0.8481 59.3608 0.9719 183.275 0.0000 Non-stationary DTII -7.82166 0.0000 152.158 0.0000 255.763 0.0000 stationary ADR -3.73620 0.0001 87.5574 0.3169 16.1008 0.9998 Non-stationary DADR -11.1203 0.0000 145.788 0.0000 114.415 0.0105 stationary LNTRD 0.91999 0.8212 74.3060 0.7150 140.930 0.0001 Non-stationary DLNTRD -10.9110 0.0000 219.253 0.0000 366.754 0.0000 stationary LNPA -0.79886 0.2122 107.136 0.0327 194.046 0.0000 Non-stationary DLNPA -10.9649 0.0000 197.803 0.0000 398.670 0.0000 stationary LNHTE -14.1213 0.0000 87.3207 0.3232 98.2773 0.1062 Non-stationary DLNHTE -12.5846 0.0000 178.211 0.0000 334.189 0.0000 stationary EDU 0.30708 0.6206 43.6456 0.9998 43.8953 0.9998 Non-stationary DEDU -21.9044 0.0000 257.289 0.0000 345.574 0.0000 stationary IND -12.7708 0.0000 2.52234 0.9942 174.054 0.0000 Non-stationary DIND -18.3810 0.0000 373.863 0.0000 411.930 0.0000 stationary LNGDP -3.33268 0.0004 83.9332 0.4200 146.301 0.0000 Non-stationary

(30)

26

DLNGDP -15.7337 0.0000 360.404 0.0000 518.668 0.0000 stationary LNPOP -0.91562 0.1799 67.1765 0.8816 242.772 0.0000 Non-stationary DLNPOP -7.12759 0.0000 109.914 0.0215 236.863 0.0000 stationary

4.2.3 KAO panel co-integration test

In the previous unit root test, all variables are stationary after first-order difference. To prevent spurious regression, this paper will conduct a panel co-integration test by performing KAO test (Kao, 1999), the results are as followed:

Table 10. KAO cointegration test

t-Statistic Prob.

ADF -3.898184 0.0077

Residual variance 0.023134

HAC variance 0.021678

From the KAO cointegration test, the statistical value is -3.898, and the corresponding p value is below 0.05. Therefore, the null hypothesis that there is no co-integration relationship should be rejected, that is to say there is a cointegration relationship among the variables, which means there is a stable equilibrium relationship over the long term.

4.3 Regression analysis

Before the regression analysis, this paper will select the type of the model by F-test and Hausman test. Firstly, conduct a F-test to see whether a mixed regression model or an

(31)

27

individual fixed-effect regression model should be established. The F statistic is defined as:

F =(SSEJ− SSEL)/(N − 1) SSEL/(NT − N − K)

Where SSEJ indicates the constraint model, which is residual sum of squares of the mixed-effects model; SSEL denotes the unconstrained model, which is the residual sum of squares of the individual fixed-effects model. The unconstrained model involves N-1 more estimated parameters than the constraint model. N stands for 41 countries; T=11 represents that 11 years of data are selected and K represents the number of selected variables. If the value of the F statistic is beyond the threshold value of (N-1, NT-N-K) at 0.05 significance level, then the hypothesis of setting up mixed-effects model should be rejected and an individual fixed-effects model should be established.

Secondly, conduct Hausman test to see if the paper should establish individual fixed-effects model or the random-fixed-effects model

H0: individual effects are independent of regression variables (individual random- effects model);

H1: individual effects are related to regression variables (individual fixed-effects models). The results as shown below:

(32)

28

Table 11. F-test and Hausman Test Test cross-section random effects

Test Summary Chi-Sq. Statistic Chi-Sq. d.f. Prob.

Cross-section random 132.5711 6 0.0000

Test cross-section fixed effects

Effects Test Statistic d.f. Prob.

Cross-section F 41.7920 (40,404) 0.0000

Cross-section Chi-square 738.1204 40 0.0000

From the F-test, it can be seen that F statistic is relatively large and the corresponding p-value is below 0.05, for which the null hypothesis of mixed-effects model should be rejected, and the fixed-effects model should be established. Besides, the P-value of Hausman test is below 0.05 as well, for which the hypothesis that the random-effects model is better than fixed-effects model should be rejected and a fixed-effects model should be established in this paper.

Since this paper selects 11 years of data from 41 countries, it is possible that different individuals have heterogeneity. Therefore, a Residual Cross-Section Dependence Test and Panel Cross-section Heteroscedasticity LR Test will be conducted in this paper, the results are shown in the following table:

(33)

29

Table 12. Residual Cross-Section Dependence Test and Panel Cross-section Heteroscedasticity LR Test

Residual Cross-Section Dependence Test

Test Statistic d.f. Prob.

Breusch-Pagan LM 1988.119 820 0.0000

Pesaran scaled LM 28.84465 0.0000

Pesaran CD 26.79465 0.0000

Panel Cross-section Heteroscedasticity LR Test

Value d.f. Prob.

Likelihood ratio 253.4396 41 0.0000

From the results, the p-value of LM test is below 0.05, for which the null hypothesis that there is no cross-sectional correlation should be rejected, which indicates that the residual sequence shows cross-sectional correlation. The p-value of LR test is below 0.05, foe which the hypothesis that there is no heteroscedasticity should be rejected, which indicates that the residual sequence has cross-sectional heteroscedasticity.

Since residual sequence has cross-sectional correlation and cross-sectional heteroscedasticity, Panel Corrected Standard Errors (Beck & Katz, 1995) will be used to estimate the parameters in this paper. To facilitate the direct impact of population ageing on technological innovation, this paper estimates the equations without interaction terms, the results are summarized in the following table:

(34)

30

Table 13. Parameter estimation result

Variable the loss of knowledge and talents knowledge spillover reverse force effect ADR 0.0936*** 0.0987*** -0.0024 (0.0309) (0.0168) (0.0250) ADR×LNTRD -0.0012 0.0029 ADR×LNPA -0.0023*** (0.0008) ADR×LNHTE 0.0037*** (0.0008) EDU 0.0172 0.0194 0.0174 (0.0122) (0.0129) (0.0113) IND -0.0101* -0.0087 -0.0102* (0.0057) (0.0054) (0.0047) LNGDP 0.4660*** 0.4441*** 0.4178*** (0.0181) (0.0197) (0.0244) LNPOP 0.7845*** 0.9149*** 0.8983*** (0.1933) (0.1817) (0.1751) C -18.9518*** -20.8970*** -20.2630*** (3.2120) (2.9787) (2.9203) F-statistic 321.0327*** 321.9110*** 321.3470*** Adjusted R-squared 0.9703 0.9700 0.9706 Obs 451 451 451

Note: Standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

From the result, population ageing does weaken technological innovation through the loss of knowledge and talents, but the effect is insignificant; population ageing has a significant negative impact for knowledge accumulation and technology accumulation

(35)

31

in technological innovation field; population ageing could promote mechanized production, thereby increasing production efficiency and positively affects technological innovation. As for control variables, education, GDP and population have a positive impact on technological innovation; the industrialization rate has a negative impact on technological innovation.

5. Conclusion

Based on the factor analysis method, this paper measures the technological innovation index of 41 countries from 2007 to 2017, and performs fixed-effects model to carry out how population ageing affect technological innovation through three effects in perspective of human capital. From the result, the scarcity of labor caused by population ageing could help increasing the output of high-tech products through the increase in productivity, thereby increasing technological innovation capacity; population ageing has a significant negative effect on skills, experience and knowledge transmission, thereby impeding technological innovation; population ageing also has a insignificant negative effect on technological innovation by reducing the proportion of high-skilled labor in the R&D department.

One limitation for this paper is that the unregistered knowledge like skills and experiences will be ignored by only using patent application as a proxy for knowledge spillover. Moreover, it is impossible to distinguish the differences in the technical and economic value of various patents, which is not rigorous enough. Another limitation is that when measuring Technological Innovation Index, to distinguish Technological

(36)

32

Innovation Index and Innovation Index and keep the causality between independent variables, this paper only take 6 factors into consideration, which can be a bit narrow. Also, Kaiser criterion is criticized for its tendency to over-extract factors (Bandalos et al., 2008). Even though this paper select limited number of factors to conduct factor analysis, for future studies, this can be solved by estimating confidence intervals (Larsen & Warne, 2010) when there are more factors taken into consideration.

In general, in terms of human capital, it takes time for elderly workers to grasp the information technology and rapidly changing knowledge. However, the consequence of the second demographic dividend is permanent. Also, learning Information technology is a process of learning- by-doing, the ability of aged workers to learn about information technology and the necessary technological skills is also growing over time. In order to maintain a sustainable technological innovation and economic growth, it would be helpful to invest more on technical skills training for all age groups when a country transform from first demographic dividend period to the second demographic dividend period.

Another thing that need to be aware of is that even though population ageing has a significant positive effect through reverse force, it has also been proved that industrialization rate has a significant negative effect on technological innovation, which proves the theory that when a country puts too much emphasis on industrial development, they may ignore things like culture, environment and policies which can cluster talents and create innovation (Von Tunzelmann, 1997). Furthermore, OECD

(37)

33

(2012) argued that if one country only chooses to develop popular but inexperienced industries like high-tech industry, then it may be costly without any benefit because of huge competition, so it is important to keep a balance between various industries.

(38)

34 References

Arrow, K. J., 1972. Economic welfare and the allocation of resources for invention.

In Readings in industrial economics: 219- 236.

Aghion, P. & Howitt, P., 1992. A Model of Growth Through Creative Destruction. Econometrica, 6(2): 323- 351.

Audretsch, D. B. & Lehmann, E. E., 2005. Does the Knowledge Spillover Theory of Entrepreneurship hold for regions? Research Policy, 34(8): 1191- 1202.

Acs, Z. J., Anselin, L. & Varga, A., 2002. Patents and innovation counts as measures of regional production of new knowledge. Research Policy, 31((7): 1069- 1085.

Ashworth, M. J., 2006. Preserving knowledge legacies: Workforce aging, turnover and human resource issues in the US electric power industry. International Journal

of Human Resource Management, 17(9): 1659- 1688.

Archibugi, D. & Coco, A., 2005. Measuring technological capabilities at the country level: a survey and a menu for choice. Research Policy, 34: 175- 194.

Adelman, I. & Morris, C.T., 1967. Society. Politics and Economic Development. The

Johns Hopkins Press.

Alazzawi, S., 2012. Innovation, productivity and foreign direct investment-induced R&D spillovers. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, 21(5): 615- 653.

Bujari, A. & Martínez, F. V., 2016. Technological Innovation and Economic Growth in Latin America. Revista mexicana de economía y finanzas, 11(2): 77- 89.

Behaghel, L. & Greenan, N., 2010. Training and age-biased technical change.

(39)

35

Behaghel, L., Caroli, E. & Roger, M., 2013. Age Biased Technical and Organisational Change, Training and Employment Prospects of Older Workers. Banque de France,1.

Baller, S., Dutta, S. & Lanvin, B., 2016. Global information technology report. Geneva:

Ouranos.

Bloom et al., 2015. Macroeconomic implications of population ageing and selected policy responses. The Lancet, 385 (9968): 649- 657

Bottazzi, L. & Peri, G., 2003. Innovation and spillovers in regions: Evidence from European patent data. European Economic Review, 47(4): 687- 710.

Bloom, D. & Williamson, J., 1998. Demographic transitions and economic miracles in emerging Asia. The World Bank Economic Review, 12(3): 419- 455.

Beck, N. L. & J. N. Katz, J. N., 1995. What to do (and not to do) with time-series cross-section data. American Political Science Review, 89: 634- 647.

Bandalos, D.L. & Boehm-Kaufman, M.R., 2008. Four common misconceptions in exploratory factor analysis. In Lance, C. E. & Vandenberg, R. J. (Eds.), Statistical and Methodological Myths and Urban Legends: Doctrine, Verity and Fable in the Organizational and Social Sciences. Taylor & Francis: 61- 87.

Crepon, B., Duguet, E. & Mairesse, J., 1998. Research, innovation and productivity: An econometric analysis at the firm level. Economics of Innovation and New

Technology, 7 (2): 115- 158

Cerny, C.A., & Kaiser, H.F., 1977. A study of a measure of sampling adequacy for factor-analytic correlation matrices. Multivariate Behavioral Research, 12(1), 43- 47.

(40)

36

Campello, M., Graham, J. R. & Harvey, C. R.,2010. The real effects of financial constraints: Evidence from a financial crisis. Journal of financial Economics, 97(3): 470- 487.

David, P. A., 1993. Intellectual property institutions and the panda's thumb: Patents, copyrights, and trade secrets in economic theory and history. Global

dimensions of Intellectual Property Rights in Science and Technology, 19- 64.

Disney, R., 1996. Can we afford to grow older? A Perspective on the economics of aging. MIT Press, Cambridge.

Dixon, S., 2003. Implications of population ageing for the labour market. Labour

Market Trends, 2.

Dickey, D.A. & Fuller, W.A., 1979. Distribution of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 74: 427- 431.

Erdal & Göçer, 2015. The Effects of Foreign Direct Investment on R&D and Innovations: Panel Data Analysis for Developing Asian Countries. Procedia - Social

and Behavioral Sciences, 195: 749- 758.

Freeman C., 1973. A Study of Success and Failure in Industrial Innovation. In

Williams, B.R. (Eds.), Science and Technology in Economic Growth. International Economic Association Conference Volumes: 227- 255.

Feyrer, J.,2007. Demographics and productivity. The Review of Economics and

Statistics, 89 (1), 100- 109.

Frosch, K. & Tivig, T., 2009. Age, human capital and the geography of innovation.

In Kuhn, M. & Ochsen, C. (Eds.), Labour Markets and Demographic Change. VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften: 137- 146.

(41)

37

Griliches, Z., 1990. Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey. Journal of

Economic Literature, 28(4): 1661- 1707.

Griliches, Z., 1979. Issues in assessing the contribution of research and development to productivity growth. The Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1): 92- 116

Griffith, R., Huergo, E., Mairesse, J. & Peters, B., 2006. Innovation and Productivity Across Four European Countries. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 22(4): 483-n498, 2006.

Galor, O., 2005. From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory. Handbook

of Economic Growth, 1: 171- 293.

Galor, O., 2012. The demographic transition: Causes and consequences. Cliometrica, 6(1): 1- 28.

Galindo, M., & Méndez-Picazo, M.-T., 2013. Innovation, entrepreneurship and economic growth. Management Decision, 51(3):501- 514.

Grossman, G. M. & Helpman, E., 1991. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. Cambridge MA, MIT Press.

Guloglu, B. & Tekin, R., 2012. A Panel Causality Analysis of the Relationship among Research and Development, Innovation, and Economic Growth in High-Income OECD Countries. Eurasian Economic Review, 2 (1): 32- 47.

Girden, E. R., 2001. Evaluating research articles from start to finish. Thousand Oaks,

Calif., Sage Publications.

Jaffe, A., Trajtenberg, M. & Henderson, R., 1993. Geographic localization of knowledge spillovers as evidenced by patent citations. The Quarterly Journal of

(42)

38

Kaiser, H. F., 1960. The application of electronic computers to factor analysis.

Educational and Psychological Measurement, 20: 141- 151.

Kuhn, M. & Ochsen, C., 2009. Labour markets and demographic change.

Wiesbaden: VS Verlag für Sozialwissenschaften.

Kuhn, M. & Hetze, P., 2007. Team composition and knowledge transfer within an ageing workforce. Rostock Center Discussion Paper.

Kao, C. D., 1999. Spurious Regression and Residual-Based Tests for Cointegration in Panel Data. Journal of Econometrics, 90: 1- 44.

Kumar, R., Stauvermann, R. & Patel, P., 2016. Exploring the link between research and economic growth: an empirical study of China and USA. Quality & Quantity, 50(3): 1073- 1091.

Lee, R. & Mason, A., 2010. Fertility, human capital, and economic growth over the demographic transition. European Journal of Population, 26(2): 159- 182.

Leonard, B. D., 1992. Core capabilities and core rigidities: a paradox in managing new product development. Strateg Manage Journal, 13: 111- 125.

Lucas, R., 2004. The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future. The Region, 18(1): 4- 20.

Lucas, R. E., 1988. On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary

Economics, 22(1): 3- 42.

Levin, A., Lin, C.F. & James, C., 2002. Unit root tests in panel data: asymptotic and finite sample properties. Journal of Econometrics,108(1): 1- 24.

Layton, D., 1991. Science education and praxis: The relationship of school science to practical action. Studies in Science Education, 19(1): 43- 79.

(43)

39

Lee, R., Mason, A. & Miller, T., 2000. Life Cycle Saving and the Demographic Transition. Population and Development Review, 26: 194- 219.

Litsareva, 2017. Success Factors of Asia-Pacific Fast-Developing Regions’ Technological Innovation Development and Economic Growth. International Journal

of Innovation Studies, 1(1): 72- 88.

Larsen, R. & Warne, R. T. (2010). Estimating confidence intervals for eigenvalues in exploratory factor analysis. Behavior Research Methods, 42(3): 871- 876.

Malthus, T. R., 1798. Essay on the Principle of Population. Electronic Scholarly

Publishing Project.

OECD, 2000. Korea and the knowledge-based economy: making the transition. OECD

Publications Services.

OECD, 2004. Science, Technology and Innovation for the 21st Century. Meeting of the

OECD Committee for Scientific and Technological Policy at Ministerial Level.

OECD, 2012. Innovation for development. A discussion of the issues and an overview

of work of the OECD directorate for science, technology and industry.

Perez, C., 2005. Technological revolutions and techno-economic paradigms.

Cambridge journal of economics.

Paul, K., 1994. An easy guide to factor analysis. London: Routledge.

Phillips, P. C. B. & Perron, P., 1988. Testing for a Unit Root in Time Series Regression.

Biometrika, 75: 335- 346.

Romer, P. M., 1987. Crazy explanations for the productivity slowdown. NBER

(44)

40

Romer, P. M., 1994. The Origins of Endogenous Growth. The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 8(1): 3- 22.

Rostow, W. W., 1962. The Stages of Economic Growth. London: Cambridge

University Press, 2: 38- 59.

Rumberger, R. W., 1981. The rising incidence of overeducation in the US labor market.

Economics of Education Review, 1(3): 293- 314.

Swan, T. W., 1956. Economic growth and capital accumulation. Economic

Record, 32(2): 334- 361.

Schumpeter, J. A., 1912. Theory of economic development. Routledge.

Scarth, W., 2002. Population aging, productivity and living standards. The Review

of Economic Performance and Social Progress, 2: 145- 156.

Snedecor, G. W. & William G. C., 1989. Statistical Methods, Eighth Edition. Iowa

State University Press.

Solow, R. M.,1956. A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly of

Economics, 70(1): 65- 94

Tian Xueyuan, Hu Weilue & Yang Yongchao,1990. Japan's population aging and economic and technological progress. - Visit to Japan and academic exchange report. China Population Science, 6: 59- 62.

Von Tunzelmann, G. N., 1997. Innovation and industrialization: A long-term comparison. Technological Forecasting & Social Change, 56(1): 1- 23.

Wang Wei & Jiang Zhenmao, 2017. The Influence of Population Aging on Technological Innovation: Based on Innovation Evaluation Using Dynamic Factor

(45)

41

Analysis and Dynamic GMM Model. Journal of Shanghai University of Finance

and Economics, 19(6): 4- 17.

Warren, T., 1929. Population. American Journal of Sociology, 34(4): 959.

World Population Prospects, 2019. United Nations, Department of Economic and

Social Affairs.

Yao Dongmin, Ning Jing & Wei Shiyan, 2017. How population ageing affects technological innovation. World Economy ,40(4):105- 128.

Zhou Guangwei & Luo sumei, 2018. Higher education input, technological innovation, and economic growth in China. Sustainability (Switzerland), 10(8).

Zachariadis, M., 2003. R&D, Innovation, and Technological Progress: A Test of the Schumpeterian Framework without Scale Effects. Canadian Journal of Economics, 36(3): 566- 586.

References

Related documents

[r]

Som slutsats kan det sägas att detta examensprojekt har varit lärorikt, till stor del tack vare skrivandet av en nybörjarmanaul då man tvingas att sätta sig in de funktioner som

In this book, I demonstrate how people in conversation (and other forms of communicative practices) on-line construct working, and re-usable, systems of linguistic resources, through

The aim of this study was to compare left ventricular ejection fraction (LVEF) results derived from gated single photon emission computed tomography (SPECT) using

Idrott och hälsa framstår generellt som ett ämne som eleverna finner intressant och en källa till glädje. Eleverna vill dessutom i stor utsträckning ha mer tid i skolan till

Submitted to Linköping Institute of Technology at Linköping University in partial fulfilment of the requirements for the degree of Licentiate of Engineering. Department of Computer

Fokus i frågorna ligger här på individens känsla av beroende till logistikorganisationen, men för att möjliggöra en djupare utvärdering har även några referensfrågor har

Genom att studera hur beslut fattas i vården givet all styrning den utsätts för, kan vi få en bättre förståelse för vilka konsekvenser olika försök till styrning faktiskt får