• No results found

Actor  responses  to  institutional   arrangements  in  Vietnam  

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Share "Actor  responses  to  institutional   arrangements  in  Vietnam  "

Copied!
332
0
0

Loading.... (view fulltext now)

Full text

(1)

     

 

Decentralizing  hydraulic  society

Actor  responses  to  institutional   arrangements  in  Vietnam  

     

Pham Thi Bich Ngoc

Linköping Studies in Arts and Science No. 577 Department of Water and Environment Studies

Linköping University Linköping 2013

(2)

Linköping Studies in Arts and Science  No. 577

Within the Falculty of Arts and Science at Linköping University, research and doctoral training is carried out within broad problem areas. Research is organized in

interdisciplinary research environments, doctoral studies mainly in research institutes.

Together they publish the series Linköping Studies in Arts and Science. This thesis comes from the Department of Water and Environmental Studies at the Tema Institute.

Distributed by:

Department of Water and Environmental Studies Linköping University

SE - 581 83 Linköping Sweden

Pham Thi Bich Ngoc

Decentralizing hydraulic society -

Actor responses to institutional arrangements in Vietnam

Cover design by Dao Thi Ngoc Bich

Edition 1:1

ISBN 978-91-7519-669-5 ISSN 0282-9800

©Pham Thi Bich Ngoc

Department of Water and Environmental Studies 2013

Printed by LiU – Tryck, Linköping, 2013

(3)

Abstract  

 

Irrigation decentralization has been launched worldwide with high expectations of improved governance, efficiency, and productivity through democratic processes. However, there is widespread recognition that decentralization is, in reality, unlikely to bring about these positive outcomes. Poor implementation is widely blamed for these failures, but the current study argues that this is only partially true. Decentralization is usually treated as a technical way of power transfer that can be evaluated through quantitative indicators. Much attention goes to searching solutions to constraints during implementation while less emphasis is on understanding of contexts, processes and the consequences of institutional changes. The common approach mainly focuses on local water users’

organizations but gives insufficient attention to the cross-level interactions between involved actors, their responses to reforms, and power relationships. This approach answers the question: what should be done, but not: why do constraints/limitations occur and why are such contradictory results obtained? In this way the approach itself diffuses some of the challenges in reality and the root of problems leading to surprise consequences and failures during implementation.

In this study, two irrigation systems in Vietnam were selected to examine the emerging decentralization processes, actors’ responses to the institutional changes, as well as the main options, challenges and constraints to decentralization. My ambition is also to further understand why constraints occur and have counter-productive effects. A mixed methods approach combining qualitative and quantitative methods, and cross-case analysis are applied. The database was built systematically, based on previous experience in this field, and participatory fieldwork.

Decentralization is regarded as a power-laden process involving not just local organizations, but also state agencies, local authorities at different levels, state irrigation companies (IDMCs), and farmers.

The study describes how institutional arrangements for decentralization have effects on the dynamics and relations of power between actors in multi-level governance, resulting in impacts on autonomy, accountability, participation, and incentives of involved actors.

The analysis shows that the legal framework and several well-intended efforts for decentralization have been launched. However, outcomes in terms of power transfer and actors’ performance are not those expected. The current institutional arrangements have created major constraints: (i) imbalanced power relations, (ii) new resource allocation mechanisms creating dependency among actors, (iii) passiveness, vested interest and privilege within state agencies and IDMCs, and (iv) free-riding behavior and distrust among farmers. Prevailing conditions defy policy intentions by finding a new version of a centralized power structure at provincial level, in which power of state agencies and IDMCs are reinforced. Unexpected effects emerge on the autonomy, accountability, participation, and incentives of all involved actors.

Decentralization of irrigation systems is a complex process, not merely a technical transfer of power.

It is hard to achieve even with policy in place. All the complexities and implications of irrigation need to be thoroughly considered, with the dynamics in society included. Evaluations of decentralization based on production and economic terms are not enough. Impacts of institutional arrangements on power relations between actors, on their incentives, maneuver room in multi-level governance, and ability to comprehend and influence processes, need to be assessed thoroughly. Essential roles remain for central government when irrigation management is decentralized.

Key words: accountability, actors, autonomy, incentives, institutional arrangements, irrigation management, participation, power relations, Vietnam.

(4)

Sammanfattning  

 

Decentralisering av bevattningsjordbruk har lanserats över hela världen med höga förväntningar på förbättrad styrning, effektivitet och produktivitet genom demokratiska processer. Men det är allmänt erkänt att decentralisering i själva verket knappast är tillräckligt för att åstadkomma dessa positiva resultat. Dåligt  genomförande har  allmänt  fått  bära skulden  för svårigheterna,  men den  aktuella   studien hävdar  att  detta bara  delvis  är sant. Decentralisering behandlas vanligtvis som ett tekniskt sätt för maktöverföring som kan utvärderas genom kvantitativa indikatorer. Mycket uppmärksamhet går då att söka lösningar på begränsningar under genomförandet medan mindre tonvikt ligger på förståelse av sammanhang, processer och konsekvenser av institutionella reformer. Fokus är främst på lokala vattenanvändarnas organisationer så att alltför lite uppmärksamhet riktas till gränsöverskridande samspel mellan berörda aktörer, deras anpassningar till reformer och maktrelationer. Detta tillvägagångssätt svarar på frågan: vad som bör göras, men inte: varför restriktioner/begränsningar uppstår och varför sådana motstridiga resultat uppnås? På så vis skymmer själva tillvägagångssättet några av de utmaningar som i verkligheten utgör grunder för de problem som leder till överraskande konsekvenser och misslyckanden under genomförandet av decentralisering.

I denna studie har två bevattningssystem i Vietnam valts ut för att undersöka framväxande decentraliseringsprocesser, aktörernas svar på de institutionella förändringar, liksom de huvudsakliga alternativ, utmaningar och hinder som finns för decentralisering. Min ambition är också att ytterligare förstå varför begränsningar förekommer och har kontraproduktiva effekter. En blandad strategi som kombinerar kvalitativa och kvantitativa metoder används för att studera gemensamma drag i fallstudierna. Databasen byggdes systematiskt, utifrån tidigare erfarenheter på detta område, och deltagande fältarbete. Decentralisering betraktas som en maktrelaterad process som involverar inte bara lokala organisationer, men också statliga myndigheter, lokala myndigheter på olika nivåer, statliga bevattningsbolag (IDMCs), och bönder. Studien beskriver hur institutionella arrangemang för decentralisering har effekter på dynamik och maktförhållanden mellan aktörer inom flernivåstyre, något som resulterar i att autonomi, ansvarsutkrävande, deltagande, och incitament för de berörda aktörerna påverkas.

Analysen visar att det rättsliga ramverket och flera välmenande insatser för decentralisering har lanserats. Men utfallet, vare sig i termer av maktöverföring eller aktörernas prestationer, är inte de förväntade. De nuvarande institutionella arrangemangen har skapat stora begränsningar: (i) obalanserade maktförhållanden, (ii) nya resursfördelningmekanismer som leder till nya beroendeformer mellan aktörer, (iii) passivitet, egenintresse och privilegier inom statliga myndigheter och IDMCs, och (iv) snålskjutsbeteende (”free-riding”) och misstro bland jordbrukarna. Rådande förhållanden går emot politiska intentioner genom att en ny version av en centraliserad maktstruktur på provinsiell nivå skapas genom att makten hos statliga myndigheter och IDMCs förstärks. Oväntade effekter uppstår då för autonomi, ansvar, delaktighet och incitament för alla inblandade aktörer.

Decentralisering av bevattningssystem är en komplex process, inte bara en teknisk överföring av makt. Den är svår att uppnå även med policy på plats. Alla komplikationer och konsekvenser av bevattning för den dynamik som ingår i samhället måste noga övervägas. Utvärderingar av decentralisering som bygger på produktion och ekonomiska termer är inte tillräckligt. Konsekvenser av institutionella arrangemang för maktrelationer mellan aktörer, för deras incitament, manöverutrymme inom ett flernivåstyre, och förmåga att förstå och påverka processer, måste bedömas noggrant. Viktiga roller återstår för staten när bevattningsjordbruk decentraliseras.

 

Nyckelord: aktörer, ansvar, delaktighet, decentralisering, incitament, institutionella arrangemang, konstbevattning, maktrelationer, självständighet, Vietnam.

(5)

 

Acknowledgements  

 

First  of  all,  I  gratefully  acknowledge  the  funding  support  from  the  Ministry   of   Agriculture   and   Rural   Development   of   Vietnam   and   its   Agricultural   Science   and   Technology   project   (AST).   I   also   thank   my   employers   in   Vietnam;   the   Vietnam   Academy   for   Water   Resources   and   its   Centre   for   Participatory  Irrigation  Management  for  providing  me  support  during  the   last  four  years.    

 

I  would  like  to  express  my  sincerest  gratitude  to  my  supervisor,  Dr.  Hans   Holmén   at   the   Department   of   Water   and   Environment   Studies   (Tema   V),   Linköping   University   and   my   co-­‐supervisor,   Prof.   Magnus   Jirström   at   the   Department  of  Human  Geography,  Lund  University.  Thank  you  both  deeply   for  your  supervision  and  encouragement  during  my  study  period.  I  would   like   to   thank   Prof.   Lotta   Andersson,   Dr.   Hans   Bertil   Wittgren,   Dr.   Anna   Jonsson,   Dr.   Anna   Bohman   at   Tema   V,   and   Dr.   Håkan   Tropp   at   the   Stockholm   International   Water   Institute   for   their   helpful   suggestions   on   the   draft   thesis.   My   special   gratitude   goes   to   Dr.   Anne   Jerneck   in   Lund   University  for  her  thoughtful  comments  in  my  final  seminar.  

 

I   greatly   appreciated   spending   my   study   at   Tema   V,   Linköping   University   because   of   its   special   interdisciplinary   and   academic   environment.   Thank   you   to   all   staff   and   doctoral   students   at   Tema   V   for   your   friendship   and   support   over   the   last   four   years.   Many   thanks   go   to   Dr.   Åsa   Danielsson,   Susanne  Eriksson,  Kerstin  Sonesson,  and  Ian  Dickson  for  all  administrative   arrangements  and  logistic  support.  I  am  also  grateful  to  staff  of  AST  project   in   Vietnam,   especially   director   Nguyen   The   Hinh,   and   accountant   Nguyen   Ha  Linh  for  their  administrative  arrangements  in  Vietnam.  Huge  thanks  go   to   Michele   Evelyn   Steele   for   her   highly   professional   editing   and   proof-­‐

reading  of  the  thesis  text.      

 

(6)

I  would  like  to  thank  colleagues,  friends  and  stakeholders  in  Vietnam  who   have  supported  me,  participated  in  the  interviews,  and  provided  valuable   inputs  to  this  research.  I  would  not  least  like  to  express  my  gratitude  to  Mr.  

Nguyen   Xuan   Tiep   who   spent   time   and   assisted   me   in   field   surveys.   My   special  thanks  are  for  the  irrigation  and  drainage  management  companies   in   Tay   Ninh   and   in   Quang   Tri   provinces;   the   irrigation   and   drainage   management  enterprises  in  Nam  Thach  Han,  Chau  Thanh  and  Trang  Bang   districts;   the   cooperatives   and   farmers   in   four   districts;   Chau   Thanh   and   Trang  Bang  districts  (Tay  Ninh),  Trieu  Phong  and  Hai  Lang  districts  (Quang   Tri).    

 

Finally,  I  would  like  to  thank  my  family  for  their  sweet  encouragements  and   great   support   over   the   years.   I   could   not   complete   my   doctoral   study   without   their   support.   My   heartfelt   gratitude   goes   to   my   father   -­‐   Pham   Ngoc   Tam,   my   mother   -­‐   Nguyen   Thi   Tram,   and   my   sister   Ha   and   brother   Hien   for   supporting   me   in   spirit.   I   am   especially   grateful   to   my   husband,   Anders   Hjort-­‐af-­‐Ornäs   and   my   daughter,   Dao   Thi   Ngoc   Bich   who   have   stayed  next  to  me  in  the  whole  journey.  Anders,  thank  you  so  much  for  your   patience   and   the   great   support   in   all   aspects   of   life.   You   are   a   person   I   always   come   to   talk   with   and   test   my   ideas.   Your   intellectual   challenges   and  comments  are  valuable  contributions  to  this  thesis.  Thank  you,  Bich  for   your  help  with  layout,  graphics,  and  computer  problems.  I  am  particularly   indebted  to  her  for  the  cover  page.    

(7)

TABLE  OF  CONTENTS      

Abstract... iii  

Sammanfattning...iv  

Acknowledgements ...v  

List  of  figures ...x  

List  of  tables ... xii  

Acronyms  and  abbreviations ...xiii  

CHAPTER  1:  INTRODUCTION...1  

1.1  Solutions,  understandings,  and  dynamics  in  water  institutional  reforms ... 1  

1.1.1  Institutional  reforms  as  solutions  to  water  crises...1  

1.1.2  Debates  around  institutional  reforms:  solutions  and  understanding ...3  

1.1.3  The  central  arguments  in  this  study ...6  

1.2  Objectives  and  research  questions ... 8  

1.3  Scope  of  study ... 9  

1.4  Outline  of  study...11  

CHAPTER  2:  POWER  TRANSFER  AS  A  PROCESS:  INTENTIONS,  APPROACHES,  AND   RESPONSES ... 13  

2.1  Good  governance  as  a  means  for  decentralization ...14  

2.1.1  Driving  forces  of  decentralization... 14  

2.1.2  Forms  and  definitions  of  decentralization ... 16  

2.1.3  Debate  about  conceptual  definitions  and  assumptions  of  decentralization ... 18  

2.1.4  Governance  and  “good”  governance ... 20  

2.2  Irrigation  decentralization:  forms,  complexities  and  implications ...23  

2.2.1  Community-­based  irrigation  management ... 25  

2.2.2  The  private  sector  and  privatization ... 27  

2.2.3  States’  roles  in  irrigation  management... 28  

2.2.4  Dynamic  process  and  powers  in  a  co-­management  form... 33  

2.2.5  Decentralization  from  polycentric  perspectives... 35  

2.3  Decentralization’s  outcomes  and  assessment  methods...37  

2.3.1  Disappointing  outcomes  and  risks  of  decentralization ... 37  

2.3.2  Poor  implementation  and  a  cause  of  failures ... 39  

2.3.3  Quantitative  assessments... 42  

2.4  Conceptual  framework  for  assessing  irrigation  decentralization...45  

2.4.1  Institutional  analysis ... 48  

2.4.2  Incentive  and  capabilities  in  responding ... 50  

2.4.3  Power  exercise  and  power  relations ... 53  

2.4.4  Accountability  and  transparency ... 57  

2.4.5  Stakeholder  participation  and  interaction ... 61  

2.5  The  analytical  framework...64  

(8)

CHAPTER  3:  METHODOLOGY,  DATA  FORMATION  AND  ANALYSIS  PROCEDURES ... 69  

3.1  Designing  research  methods...69  

3.1.1    A  mixed  methods  approach  with  a  multiple  case  study ... 69  

3.1.2  Selection  of  case  studies... 72  

3.2  Framework  and  methods  to  collect  data ...75  

3.2.1  Data  sources ... 75  

3.2.2  The  resource  base  available  for  the  study  on  interactions... 78  

3.2.3  Secondary  data  and  the  legal  documents... 81  

3.2.4  The  interviews... 82  

3.2.5  In-­depth  interviews  with  key  informants... 88  

3.2.6  Target  group  discussions ... 89  

3.2.7  Participant  observations... 91  

3.3  Procedures  in  organizing  and  processing  data ...92  

CHAPTER  4:  MULTI-­LEVEL  GOVERNANCE  IN  IRRIGATION  MANAGEMENT... 95  

4.1  Irrigation  for  productivity  and  food  security...96  

4.1.1  Irrigation  investmentand  its  contributions  to  agricultural  productivity... 96  

4.1.2  Water  challenges  and  the  sector  development  strategies...101  

4.2  Multi-­‐level  irrigation  governance ...105  

4.2.1  State  management  agencies...107  

4.2.2  State-­owned  irrigation  and  drainage  management  companies ...110  

4.2.3  Local  irrigation  management  organizations...113  

4.3  Irrigation  management  in  two  selected  cases ...120  

4.3.1  Nam  Thach  Han  irrigation  system...120  

4.3.2  Tay  Ninh  irrigation  system...126  

CHAPTER  5:  INSTITUTIONAL  REFORMS  IN  THE  IRRIGATION  SECTOR ...131  

5.1  Vietnam’s  transition  in  Doi  Moi  process...132  

5.2  Public  administrative  reforms  and  decentralization  in  irrigation...136  

5.3  Democracy,  participation  and  decentralization  of  irrigation  services...139  

5.4  Financing  irrigation...147  

5.5  Renovation  of  state-­‐owned  irrigation  management  enterprises ...151  

5.5.1  The  equitization  process ...151  

5.5.2  Financial  mechanisms...154  

5.6  Summary...157  

CHAPTER  6:  POWER  RELATIONS  AND  ACTORS’  DECISION  MAKING ...161  

6.1  Cross-­‐level  interactions  between  state  management  agencies...162  

6.1.1  Coordination  in  inconsistent  and  overlapping  mandates...163  

6.1.2  Institutional  setting  and  capacity  at  district  and  commune  levels ...171  

6.1.3  Power  at  district-­  and  commune-­level  state  agencies...173  

6.2  Interactions  between  the  state  management  agencies  and  state  irrigation  companies ...177  

6.2.1  Mobilization  and  use  of  resources...178  

6.2.2  Operation  and  maintenance  of  irrigation  systems ...179  

6.3  Interactions  between  the  state  management  agencies  and  cooperatives...182  

6.3.1  Organization  and  personnel  management ...182  

6.3.2  Mobilization  of  financial  resources ...184  

6.4  Interactions  between  state  irrigation  companies  and  cooperatives ...185  

(9)

6.4.1  Mobilization  and  use  of  resources...186  

6.4.2  Operation  and  maintenance  of  irrigation  systems ...188  

6.5  Interactions  between  cooperatives  and  farmers...192  

6.6  Power  and  the  dynamics  of  decentralization...194  

CHAPTER  7:  ACTORS’  AUTONOMY,  ACCOUNTABILITY,  AND  PARTICIPATION ...199  

7.1  Financial  autonomy...199  

7.1.1  Irrigation  and  Drainage  Management  Companies ...200  

7.1.2  Cooperatives ...209  

7.2  Accountability  and  transparency ...212  

7.2.1  State  irrigation  management  companies...213  

7.2.2  Cooperatives ...215  

7.2.3  Mechanisms  for  monitoring  and  enforcing  accountability...219  

7.3  Farmers’  participation  in  decision-­‐making...222  

7.3.1  Dominating  patterns  of  interaction ...227  

7.3.2  Communication,  information  sharing  and  transparency...228  

7.3.3  Motivation  of  farmers  in  participation...230  

7.3.4  Culture  and  passive  attitudes...231  

7.4  Reflections  on  the  assessment  of  actor  performance...233  

CHAPTER  8:  ACTORS’  RESPONSES  -­  INCENTIVES,  WILLINGNESS  AND  CAPABILITY...237  

8.1  Trade-­‐off  between  decentralization  and  contradictory  interests...237  

8.2  Privileges  and  vested  interest  in  the  new  transformed  companies ...241  

8.2.1  Organizational  adjustments  bring  internal  power  concentration...241  

8.2.2  Attitude  and  incentives  in  the  mechanism  for  public  utility...243  

8.3  Resources,  capabilities,  scales  affecting  incentives  and  accountability ...244  

8.3.1  Economics  of  scales,  income,  incentives  and  accountability ...246  

8.3.2  Capability  to  mobilize  and  access  resources ...251  

8.4  Linking  up:  Responding  to  decentralization ...257  

CHAPTER  9:  DECENTRALIZATION  POLICY  CONTEXTUALIZED  –  CHALLENGES  FOR   IRRIGATION  MANAGEMENT...259  

9.1  The  study  issues  in  the  global  debate  context ...259  

9.2  Study  findings  reflecting  on  research  questions ...261  

9.3  Reflecting  the  research  findings  to  theoretical  approaches ...267  

9.4  Study’s  implications  for  implementing  decentralization...269  

9.5  The  study  implications  for  future  study...273  

REFERENCES...275  

APPENDIXES...297  

Appendix  1.  Questionnaire  forms...297  

Appendix  2.  Stakeholder  interviews ...305  

Appendix  3.  Organizing  and  processing  data  collected...307  

Appendix  4.  List  of  policies...312  

Appendix  5.  Mandates  and  authorities  of  key  actors  in  irrigation  management...316    

(10)

List  of  figures  

 

Figure  2.1.  Simple  framework  for  assessing  irrigation  decentralization   47  

Figure  2.2.  Detailed  framework  for  assessing  irrigation  decentralization     64  

Figure  2.3.  An  analytical  framework  for  cross-­‐case  analysis  of  irrigation   decentralization    

66  

Figure  3.1.  Locations  of  two  case  studies  in  Tay  Ninh  and  Quang  Tri   province,  Vietnam  

74  

Figure  3.2.  Framework  for  collecting  data   75  

Figure  3.3.  Triangulation  of  data  from  a  multiple  source   76  

Figure  3.4.  The  fieldwork  process  to  collect  data   77  

Figure  3.5.  Target  group  discussions  with  participatory  techniques   90  

Figure  3.6.  Study  of  legal  documents  for  analyzing  irrigation   decentralization    

93  

Figure  4.1.  Yields  of  paddy  rice  in  six  regions  of  Vietnam  and  three   cropping  seasons    

100  

Figure  4.2.  Cross-­‐level  interactions  in  irrigation  management     106  

Figure  4.3.  Cross-­‐level  interplay  among  state  management  agencies   108  

Figure  4.4.  Typical  model  of  irrigation  co-­‐management  between     IDMCs,  IMEs  and  local  organizations  

110  

Figure  4.5.  The  typical  structure  of  agricultural  service  cooperatives   116  

Figure  4.6.  General  layout  of  the  Nam  Thach  Han  irrigation  system   121  

Figure  4.7.  Organizational  structure  of  Quang  Tri  IDMC   123  

Figure  4.8.  Proportions  between  two  financial  sources  in  cooperatives  in   Nam  Thach  Han  

125  

Figure  4.9.  General  layout:  Dau  Tieng  reservoir  and  irrigation  canals  in  Tay   Ninh    

127  

Figure  4.10.  The  organizational  structure  of  Tay  Ninh  IDMC   128  

Figure  5.1.  The  implementation  of  water  fees  policies  in  the  past  and  at   present  

149  

(11)

Figure  5.2.  Driving  forces  for  irrigation  institutional  reforms     158  

Figure  6.1.  Relations  between  involved  actors   161  

Figure  6.2.  Participation  and  influences  of  cooperatives  in  Tay  Ninh  and   Quang  Tri    

189  

Figure  6.3.  Irrigation  infrastructure  in  the  Tay  Ninh  system   190  

Figure  6.4.  Positions  of  actors  under  the  existing  institutional   arrangements  

195  

Figure  7.1.  Increased  revenues  of  IDMCs  for  the  period  2007-­‐2010     201  

Figure  7.2.  The  change  of  irrigated  area  in  the  studied  IDMCs   203  

Figure  7.3.  Proportions  of  expenditures  of  IDMCs   205  

Figure  7.4.  The  state  budgets  for  subsidizing  water  fees  in  2009,  2010  and   2011  during  a  period  2008-­‐2010  

208  

Figure  7.5  Proportion  of  expenditures  for  irrigation  service  in  Nam  Thach   Han  

211  

Figure  7.6.  The  performance  of  IDMC’s  staff  is  assessed  by  interviewed   farmers  and  cooperatives  

214  

Figure  7.7.  Institutional  capacity  and  performance  of  the  cooperatives  are   assessed  by  the  cooperatives  themselves  

216  

Figure  7.8.  The  performance  of  the  cooperatives  is  assessed  by  farmers             217   Figure  7.9.  The  participation  by  farmers:  Views  from  farmers  and  local  

organizations      

226  

Figure  7.10.  Farmers’  attitudes  about  participation     232  

Figure  8.1.  Number  of  households  joining  cooperatives  in  Tay  Ninh   251  

 

(12)

List  of  tables  

   

Table  2.1.  Different  types  of  irrigation  decentralization       24  

Table  2.2.  Expected  outcomes  and  impacts  of  irrigation   decentralization  

42  

Table  2.3.  Groups  of  indicators  for  assessing  outcomes  of  IMT   43  

Table  2.4.  Approaches  for  assessing  decentralization  from  three   different  processes  

46  

Table  2.5.  Power  exercise  by  actors   56  

Table  3.1.  The  number  of  questionnaire  interviews       84  

Table  3.2  Main  contents  in  the  three  sets  of  questionnaires   86  

Table  3.3.  Key  informants  and  key  information  discussed     88  

Table  4.1.  State-­‐owned  irrigation  companies  at  different  regions   112  

Table  4.2.  Main  characteristics  of  each  type  of  local  organizations   115  

Table  5.1.  Grassroots  Democratization  in  Vietnam     141  

Table  5.2.  Water  fees  regulated  in  three  different  policies  in  Quang  Tri   and  Tay  Ninh  provinces    

150  

Table  6.1.  Mandates  and  authority  of  the  state  management  agencies  in   legal  documents  

166  

Table  6.2.  Structure  of  cooperative  management  boards  in  Chau  Thanh   district    

183  

Table  7.1.  Financial  balance  from  irrigation  service  in  2011  of  13   cooperatives  in  Nam  Thach  Han  irrigation  system,  Quang  Tri  province  

210  

Table  7.2  Financial  balance  from  irrigation  service  in  2011  of  21   cooperatives  in  Chau  Thanh  and  Trang  Bang  districts,  Tay  Ninh   province  

210  

Table  7.3.  The  previous  assessments  on  main  outcomes  and  impacts  of  

irrigation  decentralization  in  Tay  Ninh  and  Nam  Thach  Han     234  

Table  8.1.  Organizational  structure  of  cooperatives  in  Nam  Thach  Han   247  

Table  8.2.  Organizational  structure  of  Cooperatives  in  Tay  Ninh     247  

 

(13)

Acronyms  and  abbreviations  

 

AC   Agricultural  Cooperative  

ADB   Asian  Development  Bank  

AFTA   Asian  Free  Trade  Area  

ASIAN   Association  of  South  East  Asian  Nations  

APEC   Asian-­‐Pacific  Economic  Cooperation  

CBNRM   Community-­‐Based  Natural  Resources  Management  

CDD   Community-­‐Driven  Development  

CECODES   Centre  for  Community  Support  and  Development  Studies    

CIEM   Central  Institute  for  Economic  Development  

CPC   Commune  People’s  Committee  

CPR   Common  Pool  Resources  

CPP   Commission  on  People’s  Petitions  of  the  Standing  Committee  for  the  

National  Assembly  of  Viet  Nam    

CSO   Civil  Society  Organization  

DANIDA   Danish  development  assistance  programmes  

DARD   Department  of  Agricultural  and  Rural  Development  

DFID   Department  for  International  Development  of  the  United  Kingdom  

DONRE   Department  of  Natural  Resources  and  Environment  

DOF   Department  of  Finance  

DOLISA   Department  of  Labor,  Invalids  and  Social  Affairs  

DPI   Department  of  Planning  and  Investment  

DPC   District  People’s  Committee  

DWR   Department  of  Water  Resources  

ESAF   Enhanced  Structural  Adjustment  Facility  

FR   The  Front  Review  of  the  Central  Committee  for  the  Viet  Nam  

Fatherland  Front  

ICWE   Dublin  Conference  on  Water  and  Environment  

IDMC   Irrigation  and  Drainage  Management  Company  

IME   Irrigation  Management  Enterprise  

IMF   International  Monetary  Fund  

IMT   Irrigation  Management  Transfer  

IPSARP   Institute  of  Policy  and  Strategy  for  Agriculture  and  Rural  

Development  

IT   Irrigation  Team  (Irrigation  Groups)  

IWRM   Integrated  Water  Resources  Management  

JICA   Japan  International  Cooperation  Program  

GDP   Gross  Domestic  Production  

GoV   Government  of  Vietnam  

GSO   General  Statistics  Office  

(14)

GMS     Greater  Mekong  Sub-­‐region  

FAO   Food  and  Agriculture  Organization    

MARD   Ministry  of  Agricultural  and  Rural  Development  

M&E   Monitoring  and  Evaluation  

MONRE   Ministry  of  Natural  Resources  and  Environment  

MOF   Ministry  of  Finance  

MOLISA   Ministry  of  Labor,  Invalids  and  Social  Affairs  

MPI   Ministry  of  Planning  and  Investment  

NGO   Non-­‐Government  Organization  

NWRC   National  Water  Resources  Council  

NRM   Natural  Resources  Management  

ODA   Overseas  Development  Agency  

O&M   Operation  and  Maintenance  

PAR   Public  Administration  Reform  

PIM   Participatory  Irrigation  Management  

PPC   Provincial  People’s  Committee  

PPP   Public-­‐Private  Partnership    

SAC   Structural  Adjustment  Credit  

SEDS   Socio-­‐Economic  Development  Strategy  

SOE   State-­‐owned  Enterprise  

UNCED   United  Nations  Conference  on  Environment  and  Development    

UNDP   United  Nations  Development  Program  

UNESCO   United  Nations  Educational,  Scientific  and  Cultural  Organization  

US   United  States  

VAWR   Vietnam  Academy  for  Water  Resources  

VFF   Vietnam  Fatherland  Front  

VND   Vietnam  Dong  

VN  GWP   Vietnam  Global  Water  Partnership  

VWRAP   Vietnam  Water  Resources  Assistance  Project  

WB   World  Bank  

WCED   World  Commission  on  Environmental  and  Development    

WGF   Water  Governance  Facility    

WUA/WUO   Water  Users’  Association/Organization  

WTO   World  Trade  Organization  

WWAP   United  Nations  World  Water  Assessment  Programme    

1  sao  =  500  m2            1  USD  =  20,000  VND  (October  2012)  

(15)

CHAPTER  1:  INTRODUCTION    

     

1.1  Solutions,  understandings,  and  dynamics  in  water   institutional  reforms  

1.1.1 Institutional reforms as solutions to water crises

Water   crises   have   become   a   major   global   concern   because   the   world’s   water   resources   are   under   pressure   in   many   places.   Water   scarcity   generally   emerges   for   several   reasons   with   two   dominating   changes   building   pressure:   limited   availability   of   water   sources   due   to   ecological   changes   with   environmental   causes,   and   dramatic   increases   in   water   demand   due   to   significant   increases   in   the   world’s   population,   urbanization,   and   new   human   activities   for   economic   development   (FAO,   2005;   Shivakotti   et   al.,   2005;   Sachs,   2008).   The   water   crises   have   been   lifted  to  the  fore  in  much  of  the  international  debates  as  a  consequence  of   ineffective   management   and   investment,   inappropriate   institutions,   and   limited  capacity  (Saleth  &  Dinar,  2004;  UNDP  WGF,  2013).  These  criticisms   have   been   associated   with   the   “patronage”   management   paradigm   that   highlights   supply-­‐driven   approach,   technical   solutions   and   infrastructure   investment,   and   centralized   management.   The   main   concerns   referred   to   the   shortcomings   of   government   bureaucracies   in   monitoring   and   enforcement,   in   accessing   information   at   local   level,   and   in   conflict   resolution.   An   overly   bureaucratic   hierarchy   generated   high   cost   for   management  and  monitoring,  in  combination  with  top-­‐down  management   that  led  to  ineffectiveness,  inefficiency,  and  inequity  in  water  allocation  and   management  (Shivakoti  et  al.,  2005).  As  a  net  result,  widespread  problems,   such   as   poor   performance,   low   return   on   investment,   an   inadequate   and   degraded   infrastructure,   and   insufficient   state   budgets,   have   been   major   unsolved  issues  in  the  water  sector  in  many  countries  (Mollinga  &  Bolding,   2004).    

(16)

An  outcome  from  the  search  for  improved  solutions  of  water  crises  is  a  new   paradigm   with   demand-­‐based   approaches   that   shifted   attention   more   to   economic   solutions,   and   decentralized   management   (Plummer   &  

Slaymaker,  2007).  Water  reforms  have  then  been  launched  on  a  worldwide   scale   since   the   1990s   as   a   response   to   the   international   initiatives   on   water1   and   to   the   pressure   from   international   lending   banks   and   many   bilateral   and   multi-­‐lateral   donors   (Mollinga   &   Bolding,   2004;   Molle   et   al.,   2009).   This   is   when   key   issues   in   water   sector   reforms   came   to   include   policy   and   institutional   reforms,   integrated   water   resources   management   (IWRM)   at   river   basin   scale,   public   participation,   and   decentralization   (Perret  et  al.,  2006).  Water  governance,  emerging  as  one  concern  from  the   broad   governance   concept   introduced   after   the   Washington   Consensus,   gives   an   emphasis   on   linkages,   partnerships,   and   processes   between   and   within  state  and  non-­‐state  entities  such  as  private  sector,  civil  society  at  all   levels   (e.g.   farm,   system,   and   basis   levels)   in   decision-­‐making   (Tropp,   2007).   Efficiency,   autonomy,   participation,   accountability,   transparency,   integrity,   and   equity   in   water   management   are   all   treated   as   general   principles  for  “good”  governance  (Roger  &  Hall,  2003).    

A   corresponding   paradigm   shift   in   irrigated   agriculture,   a   dominating   water  use  sector  in  many  agriculture-­‐based  countries,  has  followed.  Among   the  major  challenges  relating  to  water  shortage  is  an  increasing  demand  for   improved   agricultural   productivity   and   food   security   for   a   growing   population   (FAO,   2005)2.   Agricultural   diversification,   modernization   and   market-­‐orientated   crop   cultivation   in   the   situation   of   globalization   and                                                                                                                  

1  The concept of “Sustainable Development” was raised at the United Nations Conference on the Human Environment (the Stockholm Conference) in 1972 in response to the concerns about the degradation of the human environment, over-exploitation of natural resources and the consequences for economic and social development. It was re-launched by the Brundtland Commission in 1987, realizing that environment and development are intertwined and highlighting development should

“meet the needs of the present without compromising the ability of future generations” (WCED, 1987). Water reforms towards Integrated Water Resources Management (IWRM) have been embarked as a response to the key international initiatives: the Dublin Conference on Water and Environment in 1992 (ICWE 1992), the UN Conference on Environment and Development in Rio with the Agenda 21 (UNCED 1992), the Second inter-ministerial World Water Forum at the Hague in 2000  

2Population in the world is estimated to increase by about 50% over the next 50 years. Therefore, food production needs to increase double (GWP website). Irrigated areas in Asia account for about 60% of the world’s area. About 82% of a total water source is used for agriculture. The population accounts for about 50% of the world’s population. Recently, irrigation systems in the region provide water for about 41% of the total cultivated areas (FAO, 2012: 47)

(17)

high  international  market  competition  add  to  these  pressures  (WB,  2008).  

The   whole   irrigation   farming   practice   has   been   brought   policy-­‐makers   under  pressure  to  deliver  reforms  that  improve  efficiency  and  productivity.  

Following  the  consequential  policy  changes  that  move  power  from  central   bureaucratic   agencies   to   lower-­‐level   government   or   non-­‐state   entities,   decentralization   of   irrigation   management   has   been   launched   globally   to   transfer   responsibilities   in   management   and   finance   in   irrigation   systems   from   a   state   irrigation   agency   to   water   users’   organizations   or   private   sector.   The   primary   aims   are   to   bring   decision-­‐making   in   irrigation   management  closer  to  water  users  and  to  shift  payments  in  operation  and   maintenance   (O&M)   to   water   users   (Molle   et   al.,   2009).   As   a   result,   expected  outcomes  emerge  on  improved  irrigation  performance,  increased   cost   recovery,   and   reduced   the   state   financial   budget   (Garces-­‐Restrepo   et   al.,  2007).  

1.1.2 Debates around institutional reforms: solutions and understanding

The   shift   of   power   and   the   forms   for   exercising   it   at   local   water   users’  

organizations   are   known   as   the   concepts   of   Irrigation   Management   Transfer   (IMT)   and   Participatory   Irrigation   Management   (PIM),   respectively.   The   transfer   responsibility   of   water   allocation   and   management  to  private  companies/enterprises  (e.g.  in  England,  Australia)   or  to  farmers  (e.g.  in  Argentina,  New  Zealand)  is  also  implemented  under  a   form  of  privatization  (Saleth  &  Dinar,  2006).  The  processes  are  combined   and  have  been  adopted  worldwide  as  cornerstones  for  the  decentralization   efforts  in  the  irrigation  sector  (including  Vietnam).  In  spite  of  having  a  long   list  of  benefits  and  expectations  in  theory,  decentralization  in  practice  does   not  achieve  the  expected  goals  (Merrey  et  al.,  2007;  Mukherji  et  al.,  2009b).  

Earlier   experience   and   empirical   studies   underscore   how   difficult   it   is   to   make   decentralization   work   in   practice.   The   processes   are   assessed   as   incomplete   (Vemillions,   1997),   and   their   outcomes   are   very   mixed   (Mukherji   et   al.,   2009a).   In   fact,   many   established   water   users’  

organizations   (WUOs)   under   the   IMT/PIM   process   ceased   to   function   as   soon   as   the   external   support   from   donor-­‐funded   projects   closed   (Bandaragoda,  2006).    None  of  the  tested  forms  of  decentralization  (i.e.  the   devolution,   privatization,   decentralization,   partnership)   have   brought   about  the  expected  outcomes  (Meinzen-­‐Dick,  2007).    

(18)

In  many  instances,  water  institutional  reforms  have  even  been  seen  as  the  

“ceremonial  and  cosmetic”  processes  because  they  have  been  implemented   in  incomplete  and  fragmented  institutions,  and  at  policy  level  only  (Saleth  

&   Dinar,   2006).   One   area   of   controversy   in   the   literature   is   around   the   concern  why  many  cases  have  failed.  But  no  comprehensive  conclusion  has   as  yet  been  drawn  from  these  debates  (Callejo  &  Cossio,  2009).  In  much  of   the   previous   research   (cf.   Burman,   2001;   Saleth   &   Dina,   2004;   Sengupta   2005;   Barker   &   Molle,   2005;   Bandaragoda,   2006;   Garces-­‐Restrepo   et   al.  

2007;   Mukherji   et   al.,   2009a),   poor   implementations   are   often   seen   as   a   main  cause  for  reforms’  failures.  Examples  include  poor  preparation  and  an   improper   legal   framework,   a   lack   of   capacity   and   limited   participation   of   stakeholders,   strong   interventions   of   donors,   a   lack   of   political   commitments,   and   resistance   of   the   powerful   actors.   Policy   recommendations   for   achieving   effective   decentralization,   therefore,   put   the   emphasis   on   enabling   legal   frameworks   to   empower   and   enhance   capacity   within   local   organizations,   and   to   set   up   a   mechanism   for   public   participation  (WB,  2008).    

However,   with   experience   from   limited   outcomes   in   many   donor-­‐funded   projects  (Mollinga  &  Bolding,  2004),  the  question  of  what  should  be  done  to   maintain  long-­‐term  success  with  decentralization,  and  even  how  it  should   be  implemented,  seems  to  remain  unanswered.  In  actual  fact,  there  is  also   no   consensus   among   the   researcher   and   donor   communities   about   the   proper   form   of   water   governance   (Plummer   &   Slaymaker,   2007).   A   widespread   application   of   decentralization   in   public   sectors   and   natural   resources   management   today   is   associated   with   the   ambition   to   achieve   good   governance,   efficiency,   and   development.   This   representation   of   decentralization  as  intrinsically  good  has  become  a  global  mantra  over  the   last   decades.   However,   this   concept   needs   to   be   challenged   since   decentralization  in  practice  does  not  always  achieve  the  expected  goals  and   is   not   always   efficient   in   affecting   economic   of   scale   and   overall   coordination  even  through  having  a  long  list  of  benefits  and  expectations  in   theory  (cf.  Litvack  et  al.,  1998;  Campos  &  Hellman,  2005;  WB,  2008).    

In   a   broader   debate   around   water   reforms   than   irrigated   agriculture,   the   concepts   of   decentralization   and   governance   have   been   heavily   criticized  

(19)

with  regards  to  their  inconsistent  definitions,  misleading  assumptions  and   shortcomings   in   applications   (Cohen   &   Peterson,   1997;   Plummer   &  

Slaymaker,   2007).   Governance   is   associated   with   a   critique   of   ideological   presumption   of   neoliberal   economic   policies   about   democracy   and   development   based   on   a   free   market   economy   and   private   sectors   as   a   means   of   achieving   economic   growth   (cf.   Gunnarsson   &   Holmén,   1995;  

Mehrotra,   2006).   In   spite   of   emphasizing   partnerships   between   state   and   non-­‐state  entities,  and  processes  in  social,  economic,  political  domains,  two   application   consequences   of   governance   have   been   questioned—a   lack   of   socio-­‐political   context   and   an   over-­‐emphasis   of   legal   arrangements.   “A   social   engineering   approach”   and   a   widespread   application   of   blueprint   models  in  many  donor-­‐funded   projects   focus   more   on   administrative   and   technical   aspects   than   social   and   political   contexts   (Merrey   et   al.,   2007).  

Institutional   reforms   place   an   emphasis   on   formal   institutions   and   legal   frameworks   (i.e.   laws,   policies,   and   organizational   restructure),   but   informal   organizations   and   institutions   (i.e.   customary   behavior,   norms,   incentives  of  actors,  social  relations,  traditions  and  the  process  of  cultural   changes)  are  usually  ignored  (Sokile  et  al.,  2005;  Saleth,  2005;  Molle  et  al.,   2009).   There   is   also   a   widespread   lack   of   attention   to   the   dynamics   in   institutional   evolution   and   power   structure   in   multi-­‐level   interaction   processes  (Saleth  &  Dinar,  2004;  Clement  2010;  2013).  Consequently,  these   limitations  create  a  fundamental  misunderstanding  of  the  nature  of  social   organizations  and  incentives  of  actors  in  collective  actions  (Cleaver  2002).    

In  my  reading  of  the  literature,  this  has  brought  research  communities  and   donors  to  focus  on  global  reform  trends  with  prime  attention  to  searching   solutions   to   constraints   during   implementation   and   less   emphasis   on   understanding   contexts,   dynamic   processes,   and   the   consequences   of   institutional  changes.  In  my  opinion,  the  main  focus  of  many  researchers,   practitioners,   and   donors   is   on   what   should   be   done   but   not   on   why   constraints/limitations   occur   and   why   such   contradictory   results   are   obtained.  It  would  be  a  reason  why  there  is  a  lack  of  critical  evaluations  by   many   donors   of   the   applications   of   blueprint   models   (Plummer   &  

Slaymaker,   2007)   and   of   the   failures   of   many   cases   (Mollinga   &   Bolning,   2004).  As  for  its  research  focus,  the  current  study  is  intended  to  illustrate   how   necessary   both   aspects;   solutions   and   understandings   are   to   the   implementation   of   sustainable   decentralization.   My   suggestion   is   that  

References

Related documents

Although the concept promises great benefits for the industry and the environment, and much attention has been given to waste management in construction and the transition towards

The persons seated at the table must be informed so they do not appear on several seatings Please print clearly.. Specialization

Hence, the positive effects of democracy aid on democratic development found in previous studies seem to be restricted to changes in democracy levels within regimes

The first two papers of this dissertation show that democracy aid may have positive effects on democracy levels and regime change but that the effects are limited to

The Nordic Gender Effect at Work briefs share the collective Nordic experience in investing in gender equality including parental leave, childcare, flexible work

This thesis aim to find out if the school principals who perceived that they had high levels of flexible work arrangements, (i.e. arrangements that allows an employ- ee to alter

This paper shows that in the organisation studied, there is a general approach towards managing conflict situations, regardless of the conflict type that exists, in this

Diagram 4 visar den totala mängden direktinvesteringar som registrerats för användning i olika projekt från slutet av 1980-talet till 2014.. Detta diagram visar